An Organizational Perspective on Patenting and Partnering: Unpacking Capacities to Manage Participation in Patent Pools

Date01 September 2019
Published date01 September 2019
AuthorJamal‐Eddine Azzam
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/emre.12188
An Organizational Perspective on Patenting
and Partnering: Unpacking Capacities to
Manage Participation in Patent Pools
JAMAL-EDDINE AZZAM
TSM-Research, Université Toulouse Capitole, CNRS, Toulouse, France
In this research, we investigate how firms manage their participation in patent pools, which are private
interorganizationalarrangements for sharingpatents on a large scale.Drawing on the licensing andopen innovation
literature,we develop a conceptual framework to analyze theorganizational capacities thatenable firms to manage
their participation in patent pools. We illustrate and enrich this conceptual framework through anin-depth study of
Technicolor. Our findings show that the company develops and leverages its patent portfolio to strengthen its
positions both as a licenseeand licensor vis-à-vis the poolsmembersthrough two articulatedcapacities: absorptive
and desorptive.We also revealhow the company assesses opportunities to join patentpools and continues to integrate
more patents. The organizational perspective articulated in this paper enhances the understanding of patent pools
and expands the literature on licensing and open innovation.
Keywords: patent pools; organizational capacities;licensing; open innovation
Introduction
Firms increasingly use patents to develop and sustain
competitive advantages in a knowledge-based economy
(Grindley and Teece, 1997; Pitkethly, 2001; Somaya,
2012). Early research rooted in economics and law showed
the relative inefficiency of patents as an appropriation
mechanism (Levin et al., 1987; Cohen et al., 2002).
Management research has revealed that patents are
valuable not only as resources for achieving strategic goals
beyond simple protection but also as sources of
organizational capacities that affect firm performance (Hall
and Ziedonis, 2001; Blind et al., 2006; Somaya et al.,
2007; Gambardella et al., 2008; Reitzig and Puranam,
2009; Reitzig and Wagner, 2010; Greenberg, 2013; Hsu
and Ziedonis, 2013; Korkeamäki and Takalo, 2013).
Management scholars have highlighted that many firms
evolve in multi-invention contexts characterized by
technologically complex standards and products with
multiple components that have been individually patented
by independent actors (Teece et al., 2011; Granstrand and
Holgersson, 2013). Developing complex innovative
products thus requires managing the tension between
technology integration (i.e., the use of many different
technologies from different domains) and patent
fragmentation (i.e., a dense web of overlapping patents that
are individually owned) while avoiding the risk of patent
infringement (Somaya, 2012; Di Minin and Faems,
2013). Managing this tension involves collaborative
arrangements among the patent holders regarding all the
elements involved in standards and products (Shapiro,
2001; Lerner and Tirole, 2004; Vakili, 2016).
Firms increasingly use patent pools as collaborative
arrangements to a ddress patent fragm entation challenges.
A patent pool is an agreement between two or more
patent holders to cross-license their patents in a specific
field and to license all pooled patents to third parties.
Patent pools are one-stop shopsthat facilitate the
large-scale licensing and promotion of a technological
standard (Joshi and Nerkar, 2011; Rayna and Striukova,
2010; Vakili, 2016). Competition authorities encourage
the use of modern patent pools to promote both
innovation and competition (United States Department
of Justice (U.S. DOJ) and Federal Trade Commission
(FTC), 2007); patent pools have spread to many sectors,
thereby establishing economic significance (Lerner
et al., 2007; WIPO, 2011;de Uijl et al., 2013).
1
Empirical
evidence showsthat the formation of patent pools reduces
Correspondence: Jamal-Eddine Azzam, TSM-Research, University
ToulouseCapitole, 2,rue du Doyen Gabriel MartyFrance,31000Toulouse,
France. E-mailjamal-eddine.azzam@tsm-education.fr
1
In the mid-2000s, the income generated in the United States from sales of
products incorporating technologiesrelated to patent pools exceeded US$100
billion peryear (Clarkson & Dekorte, 2006).
DOI: 10.1111/emre.12188
©2018 European Academy of Management
European Management Review, Vol. 16, 699, (2019)
71 7
77
both technological and appropriation uncertainties for
firms and increases the rate of follow-on innovations
based on pooled patents (Vakili, 2016).
Due to the economic significance and widespread
diffusion of patent pools, economics and management
scholars have investigated the antecedents and
consequences of their formation (Lerner and Tirole,
2004, 2007; Lerner et al., 2007; Baron and Pohlman,
2011; Layne-Farrar and Lerner, 2011; Lévêque and
Ménière, 2011; Joshi and Nerkar, 2011; Vakili, 2016).
To date, few scholars have thoroughly examined how
firms manage their participation in patent pools. To the
best of our knowledge, de Uijl et al. (2013) were the first
to investigate the management of patent pools when
technologies become increasingly complex. However,
their unit of analysis was the pool, notparticipating firms,
thus their findings do not indicatehow firms manage their
participation. Such participation can be challenging since
firms must balance the tradeoff between value creation
and value capture(Vakili, 2016). Therefore,it is important
to understand which capacities firms need to successfully
manage their participation in patent pools. Thus, we ask
the following:which capacities do firms deployto manage
participation in patent pools, and how do these capacities
interact? Addressing this issue can expand the existing
literature on patent pools and help both scholars and
managers better understand patent management in
situations of ownership fragmentation and technological
complexity (Teece et al., 2011; Di Minin and Faems,
2013; Somaya, 2012).
First, we develop a conceptual framework of the
capacities involved in managing patent pool participation
by building on related but disconnected research streams
connected with licensing and open innovation. Then, we
enrich this framework with findings from qualitative
fieldwork at Technic olor, a worldwide technolo gy leader
in the media and entertainment industries. Since the
company has participated in several patent pools since
2002, it provides an appropriate context for a case study
aimed at refining the conceptual framework. Using a
qualitative designto analyze firmsparticipation in patent
pools is consistent with recent calls in the literature
encouraging the use of case study research to understand
the mechanisms and processes by which firms develop
and deploy patent management capacities (Candelin-
Plamqvist et al., 2012; Somaya, 2012).
The core contributionof this paper is the elaboration of
a framework that clarifies how firms could manage their
participation in patent pools. The framework highlights
two organizational capacities (absorptive and desorptive)
and shows how they are deployed as well as how they
interact to manage different aspects of participation in
patent pools (e.g., by developingand defending the firms
patent portfolioand supporting its interestsas a licensee as
well as a licensor). In addition to addressing an
unexplored facet of patent pools, our paper adds two
insights tothe existing studies that analyzethe antecedents
and consequences of poolsformation. On the one hand,
the paper reveals an unidentified parameter affecting
firmsdecisions to join pools and thus completes the
understanding of fac tors that influence firmsparticipation
in pools. On the other hand, the paper reveals the
organizationaldynamics that explain when andhow firms
integrate more patents in pools. Furthermore, the paper
contributes to the literature on licensing and open
innovation by showing how licensing-out and licensing-
in capacities interact and mutually reinforce each other.
Literature review
Patent pools are private collaborative arrangements
through which firms share their patents and collectively
license them to third parties (Lerner and Tirole, 2004;
Lerner et al., 2007). Patent pools represent multilateral
licensing agreements involving multiple firms (patents
holders and other licensees) and are explicitly approved
by regulators to avoid the tragedy of the anticommons,
accelerate the adoption of technological standards, and
facilitate interactions between licensors and licensees (de
Uijl et al., 2013). Figure 1 illustrates how patent pools
function.
Patent pools foster the development of nascent
technological standards and subsequent innovation by
promoting access to essential patents under fair,
reasonable and non-discriminant (FRAND) conditions
(Vakili, 2016). Patents for inventions that comprise
technological standards and are important for developing
standards-compliant products are considered standard-
essential(Shapiro, 2001; Lerner and Tirole, 2007;
Bekkers et al., 2012;Baron and Delcamp, 2015). A patent
is standard-essential when there are no technological
alternatives to the invention it protects, meaning that it is
not possible to develop standards-compliant products
without patent infringement. Hence, patent pools offer
advantages by providing both licensors and licensees
collective access to essential patents, thereby reducing
transaction costs, improving rent collection, reducing the
risk of hold-ups, etc.
Figure 1 Operatingmode of a patent pool.
700 J.-E. Azzam
©2018 European Academy of Management

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT