Bank liquidity, macroeconomic risk, and bank risk: Evidence from the Financial Services Modernization Act

AuthorYu‐Yi Lee,Yong‐Chin Liu,I‐Ju Chen
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12208
Published date01 January 2020
Date01 January 2020
DOI: 10.1111/eufm.12208
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Bank liquidity, macroeconomic risk, and bank risk:
Evidence from the Financial Services
Modernization Act
I-Ju Chen
1
|
Yu-Yi Lee
1
|
Yong-Chin Liu
2
1
Discipline of Finance, College of
Management, Yuan Ze University,
Taoyuan, Taiwan
Emails: ijchen@saturn.yzu.edu.tw;
s1017441@mail.yzu.edu.tw
2
Department of Finance, College of
Management, Asia University, Taichung,
Taiwan
Email: chinyda@asia.edu.tw
Funding information
Ministry of Science and Technology in
Taiwan (MOST 106-2632-H-155-001; 106-
2410-H-155-005-MY2)
Abstract
We investigate the empirical relationship between macro-
economic risk, bank liquidity, and bank risk surrounding the
1999 Financial Services Modernization Act. We propose
that bank risk and liquidity are positively related as
macroeconomic risk increases, and that this effect is
particularly strong after the GrammLeachBliley Act
(GLBA). We test our hypotheses by collecting data from
1994 to 2006 for banks in the United States. The results
show that banks flush with liquid assets in a high
macroeconomic risk environment conducted more lending
activities following the enactment of the GLBA, leading to
higher bank risk. Our study complements the understanding
of bank liquidity management.
KEYWORDS
bank liquidity, bank risk, Financial Services Modernization Act
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G21, G30
We would like to thank John A. Doukas (the Editor), the anonymous referees, Sheng-Syan Chen, Yanzhi Wang, Yan-Shing
Chen, and participants at the 2015 FMA conference for very insightful comments and helpful suggestions. I-Ju Chen
acknowledges funding from the Ministry of Science and Technology in Taiwan (MOST 106-2632-H-155-001; 106-2410-H-
155-005-MY2). All errors are our own.
Eur Financ Manag. 2019;133. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm © 2019 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
|
1
143Eur Financ Manag. 2020;26:143–175. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm © 2019 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
EUROPEAN
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Commercial banks that serve as financial intermediaries engage in deposit-taking and lending
activities. Banks must be able to disburse their payments at any time, as depositors withdraw from their
accounts on a first-come, first-serve basis. Meanwhile, banks provide loans to borrowers, creating
liquidity for those in need. As depositors can withdraw funds on demand, and banks must also fulfill
obligations to loan borrowers as necessary, banks face liquidity risks from both the asset and liability
sides (Gatev, Schuermann, & Strahan, 2009). Liquidity risk typically refers to the probability that a
bank with insufficient liquidity, usually including cash and marketable assets or other forms of near-
cash assets, cannot pay its short-term obligations as they come due. This inability will lead to financial
problems for banks and ultimately a bank run (Diamond & Dybvig, 1983; Hong, Huang, & Wu, 2014;
Ratnovski, 2013).
However, the liquidity problem among banks during the crisis highlighted the importance of
liquidity holding, which had not been emphasized before the 20072009 crisis. For example,
Morkoetter, Schaller, and Westerfeld (2014) find that failing banks have different liquidity positions
from non-failing banks at least 5 years prior to default. Calomiris, Heider, and Hoerova (2015) develop
a theoretical model of the bank liquidity requirement and suggest that it is held voluntarily as a
commitment device to manage risk properly and cash reserve requirements are needed to incentivize
prudent behaviors by banks. Furthermore, the Basel III accord introduces global liquidity standards to
ensure the ability of an institution to withstand a severe liquidity freeze and to address liquidity
mismatches (Allen & Gale, 2017; Du, 2017).
Recent studies suggest that bank liquidity not only acts as a bufferagainst unexpected shocks
from the business environment, but also affects the degree of banksrisk-taking incentives. Acharya
and Naqvi (2012) argue that commercial banks assume more risk and make excessive loans when they
have abundant liquidity, as their payoffs are based on the loans advanced. When the market experiences
a downturn, depositorslack of confidence in capital market investments compels them to deposit
funds in financial institutions. Because a flight to safety takes place, commercial banks in this situation
receive abundant funds and liquidity during a market recession. In addition, deposit insurance creates a
moral hazard for excessive risk-taking by banks (Keeley, 1990). They then begin to pay less attention to
the quality of loans and make excessive loans. This leads to higher bank risk or even a crisis (Acharya &
Naqvi, 2012; Gatev & Strahan, 2006). Wagner (2007) theoretically shows that higher liquidity can
increase the instability of the banking system and may lead to bank failure. Similar to Acharya and
Naqvi (2012) and Wagner (2007), Khan, Scheule, and Wu (2017) find that banks take higher risks
when they have lower liquidity funding risk.
This study provides empirical evidence for Acharya and Naqvi's (2012) theoretical proposition
about bank liquidity and the risk-taking behaviors of commercial banks in the United States during
19942006. In addition, we also expect that the passage of the 1999 Financial Services Modernization
Act (also known as the GrammLeachBliley Act; hereafter, GLBA), which liberalized the firewall
between commercial and investment banks and created more flexibility in the financial industry's
provision of services, would strengthen the relationship between bank liquidity and such risk-taking
behaviors. Because the GLBA allows different types of financial institutions to become involved in
new business activities, banks are eager to provide a variety of products to meet customersfinancial
needs and increase their profits (Santomero, 2001; Stiroh, 2006; Stiroh & Rumble, 2006). Commercial
banks faced with the pressure of intense competition will attempt to develop a more effective business
model by launching high-volume, low-cost ventures (Berger, Frame, & Miller, 2005; Carter &
McNulty, 2005). In addition, advances in technology and the development of the securitization market
enable banks to liquidate their illiquid loans through the securitization market (Loutskina, 2011). This
2
|
CHEN ET AL.
d
a
p
l
e
t
o
G
F
p
l
(
1
e
l
l
t
b
s
f
g
b
i
i
i
h
o
r
S
2
H
2
C
l
K
d
u
d
l
c
C
H
1152 HEATON
144
C
CHEN ET AL.
|
EUROPEAN
g
r
g
l
y
a
-
l
;
f
,
s
p
a
e
o
y
s
a
y
s
t
n
a
o
&
n
d
s
n
g
n
l
s
g
n
l
l
s
&
t
s
L
.
development also induces banks to pay less attention to shortfalls in liquidity and makes them more
aggressive in loan making. The increase in liquidity or funds encourages managers to think that the
potential profits from loan making outweigh the potential losses due to defaults. Managerial neglect of
loan quality raises the bank risk and therefore the relationship between bank liquidity and bank risk is
expected to be particularly strong when the macroeconomic risk is high.
We test our hypotheses by obtaining data from the Compustat database for all banks operating in
the United States between 1994 and 2006. Our empirical findings show that banks with large amounts
of liquid assets during a market recession conducted more lending activities after the enactment of the
GLBA, leading to higher bank risk in an environment that already had high macroeconomic risk.
Further, our results are robust to different measures of bank risk, bank liquidity, extension of sample
period, and different research models controlling for the endogeneity issue in bank liquidity.
This study makes two valuable contributions to the literature. First, our study complements the
literature on bank liquidity. Although researchers have highlighted the unique role of bank liquidity
(Diamond & Dybvig, 1983; Gatev & Strahan, 2006; Kashyap, Rajan, & Stein, 2002; Myers & Rajan,
1998), few studies empirically investigate the effect of bank liquidity on bank risk-taking behavior,
except for Khan et al. (2017). They document that banks take more risk when they have lower funding
liquidity risk proxied by deposit ratios. Our empirical evidence further shows that banks flush with
liquid assets in a high macroeconomic risk environment conducted more lending activities following
the enactment of the GLBA, leading to higher bank risk, confirming the theoretical argument suggested
by Acharya and Naqvi (2012), Berger, Bouwman, Kick, and Schaeck (2016), and Wagner (2007). Our
study also implies that commercial banksliquidity management is one reason for the 20072009
financial crisis, and that banks should contemplate liquidity management under the new Basel III
guidelines when macroeconomic risks rise.
Second, our study also documents that the GLBA leads to an increase in banksrisk-taking
behaviors, and that this effect is particularly strong for high-liquidity banks when macroeconomic risk
is high. As the passage of the GLBA eliminated the distinctions between different types of financial
institutions and dramatically changed the market for financial services (Geyfman & Yeager, 2009), the
intense competition triggered within the banking industry provides a natural laboratory for examining
how banks facing environmental change after the GLBA changed their liquidity policy and the effect
on bank risk. Therefore, our study also complements the literature on the effect of the GLBA.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. We review the literature and discuss our
research hypotheses in section 2. Section 3 describes the methodology and its summary statistics.
Section 4 presents our empirical results and the final section concludes.
2
|
LITERATURE REVIEW AND DEVELOPMENT OF
HYPOTHESES
2.1
|
The relationship between bank liquidity and bank risk-taking
Commercial banks serve as an intermediary for financial markets engaging in deposit-taking and
lending activities to provide market liquidity (Diamond & Dybvig, 1983; Diamond & Rajan, 2000;
Kashyap et al., 2002). Because of this specific role, they are required to hold sufficient liquidity to meet
depositorswithdrawal needs (Gatev et al., 2007; Kashyap et al., 2002; Loutskina, 2011), need for
unexpected conversion of illiquid to liquid assets (Acharya, Shin, & Yorulmazer, 2011), and the
difficulties with raising external finance (Morris & Shin, 2008), among other reasons. Therefore,
liquidity management has emerged as a risk management method for avoiding bank runs or liquidity
crises (Diamond & Dybvid, 1983; Ratnovski, 2013).
CHEN ET AL
|
3
HEATON 1151
N
145
CHEN ET AL
L
.EUROPEAN
|

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT