Consumption, asset wealth, equity premium, term spread, and flight to quality

Published date01 June 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12243
AuthorMauro Costantini,Ricardo M. Sousa
Date01 June 2020
Eur Financ Manag. 2020;26:778807.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm778
|
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
DOI: 10.1111/eufm.12243
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Consumption, asset wealth, equity premium,
term spread, and flight to quality
Mauro Costantini
1
|
Ricardo M. Sousa
2,3
1
Department of Industrial and
Information Engineering and Economics,
University of L'Aquila, L'Aquila, Italy
2
Department of Economics and
Economic Policies Research Unit (NIPE),
Gualtar Campus, University of Minho,
Braga, Portugal
3
LSE Alumni Association, Houghton
Street, London School of Economics and
Political Science, London, United
Kingdom
Correspondence
Ricardo M. Sousa, University of Minho,
Department of Economics and Economic
Policies Research Unit (NIPE), Campus
of Gualtar, Braga, Portugal; London
School of Economics and Political
Science, LSE Alumni Association,
Houghton Street, London WC2 2AE,
United Kingdom.
Email: rjsousa@eeg.uminho.pt and
rjsousa@alumni.lse.ac.uk
Abstract
We link transitory deviations of consumption from its
equilibrium relationship with aggregate wealth and labor
income to equity returns on the one hand, and to two
characteristics of bond investorsthe premium de-
manded to hold longterm assets, and flight to quality
behavioron the other hand. Using a panel of 10 euro
area countries over the period 1984Q12017Q4, we show
that a rise in the consumptionwealth ratio predicts both
higher equity returns and the future term spread, while a
fall in the consumptionwealth ratio explains a large
fraction of the rise in the spread between the riskyand
the safehavenbond.
KEYWORDS
asset wealth, consumption, flight to quality, labor income, panel data,
term premium
JEL CLASSIFICATION
C33; E21; E44; D12
EUROPEAN
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT
We are grateful to the Editor, John Doukas, and an anonymous referee, to participants in the 26th International
Conference on Forecasting Financial Marketsand the 50th Anniversary Conference of the Money, Macro and
Finance (MMF) Group at the London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE), to seminars and discussions at
Queen Mary University of London and Lille University, and to Deven Bathia, Benoît Demil, Alain Desreumax, Brigitte
Granville, Praveen Gupta, Fredj Jawadi, Eleni Lioliou, Lin Ma, Sushanta Mallick, Pedro Martins, and Gulnur
Muradoglu, for their constructive comments and suggestions that considerably improved this paper. NIPE's work is
financed by National Funds of the FCTPortuguese Foundation for Science and Technology within project UID/
ECO/03182/2019.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
A wellestablished body of the finance literature builds the theoretical linkage and explores the
empirical relationship between the dynamics of macroeconomic activity and asset wealth. Some
authors start with a capital asset pricing model (CAPM) and emphasize that the (equity) risk
premium reflects an asset's ability to insure against unfavorable consumption fluctuations
(Lintner, 1965; Sharpe, 1964). Seminal studies also rely on the concept of discounted present
value and derive structural associations between macroeconomic data and future equity returns
(Campbell, 1996; Campbell & Shiller, 1987).
Other authors enrich the standard CAPM model with additional factors that improve asset
pricing accuracy. These include the threefactor (i.e. market, size, and value risks) model of
Fama and French (1992); the fourfactor models of Carhart (1997) and Pastor and Stambaugh
(2003), which add momentum and liquidity risks, respectively, to the threefactor model; the
fivefactor model of Fama and French (2015), which includes operating profitability and
investment in the threefactor model; the sixfactor model of Fama and French (2018), which
adds momentum to the fivefactor model; the fourthquarter consumption growth model of
Jagannathan and Wang (2007); and the financial intermediaries' leverage factor model of
Adrian, Etula, and Muir (2014).
Along the same lines, but more recently, new factor pricing models have tried to explain the
crosssection of expected equity returns. Starting with the inclusion of market and size factors,
the four‐“mispricing”‐factor model of Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) adds management and
performance risks; the
q
factor model of Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2015) incorporates the
investmenttoassets ratio and the return on equity, and the
q
5
factor model of Hou, Mo, Xue,
and Zhang (2019) accounts for expected growth in the
q
factor model. Singlefactor models,
such as those by Kuehn, Simutin, and Wang (2017), Wen (2019) and Lettau, Ludvigson, and Ma
(2019), focus on labor search frictions, aggregate asset growth, and capital share risk,
respectively. Finally, the threefactor model of Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Sun (2019) contains
market, (net share issuance) financing and postearningsannouncementdraft risks.
Yet, given the CAPM's difficulty in matching differences in the covariance of equity returns
and contemporaneous consumption growth with differences in expected equity returns (Fama
& French, 1992; Hansen & Singleton, 1982),
1
some research highlights the role of longterm
risks (Bansal & Yaron, 2004; Bansal, Dittmar, & Lundblad, 2005, 2016; Parker & Julliard, 2005):
risk compensation should mirror the exposure of longterm consumption to the full path of
future cashflows and discount rates (Campbell, Polk, & Vuolteenaho, 2010; Campbell &
Vuolteenaho, 2004). These are the pillars of the intertemporal capital asset pricing model
(Campbell, 1993).
2
Another research avenue reconciles the joint dynamics of consumption growth and
equity returns by delving into alternative specific preferences of the representative
investor (Campbell & Cochrane, 1999; Constantinides, 1990; Pakos, 2011; Piazzesi,
Schneider, & Tuzel, 2007; Yogo, 2006). These studies lie at the heart of consumption
1
As noted by Antoniou, Doukas, and Subrahmanyam (2016), such inability could reflect the stronger presence of overconfident and unsophisticated traders
during optimistic periods and less noise trading during pessimistic periods.
2
For a critical assessment of the CAPM model, see Levy (2010) and Zhang (2017). Subrahmanyam (2010) evaluates crucial aspects of stock return predictability,
including correlational structure and heterogeneity of controls and methodology. Barillas and Shanken (2018) compute Bayesian probabilities for all asset
pricing models based on subsets of a given number of candidate traded factors. They show that models including momentum, value, and profitability factors
tend to dominate.
COSTANTINI AND SOUSA EUROPEAN
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT
|
779

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT