Diversification, Size and Risk: the Case of Bank Acquisitions of Nonbank Financial Firms
DOI | http://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12061 |
Date | 01 March 2016 |
Published date | 01 March 2016 |
Diversification, Size and Risk: the Case
of Bank Acquisitions of Nonbank
Financial Firms
Barbara Casu
Cass Business School, City University, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, UK
E-mail: b.casu@city.ac.uk
Panagiotis Dontis‐Charitos
Westminster Business School, University of Westminster, 35 Marylebone Road, London NW1 5LS, UK
E-mail: p.dontis-charitos@westminster.ac.uk
Sotiris Staikouras
Cass Business School, City University, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, UK
E-mail: sks@city.ac.uk
Jonathan Williams
Bangor Business School, Bangor University, Hen Goleg, College Road, Bangor LL57 2DG, UK
E-mail: jon.williams@bangor.ac.uk
Abstract
We investigate the risk effects of bank acquisitions of insurance companies and
securities firms between 1991 and 2012 using a newly constructed dataset of M&A
deals. We examine risk changes before and after deal announcements by decompos-
ing risk into systematic and idiosyncratic components. Subsequently, we investigate
the relationship between risk and diversification by modelling the determinants of
risks. We find that bank combinations with securities firms yield higher risks than
combinations with insurance companies. Bank size is an important and consistent
determinant of risk whereas diversification is not. Our results inform the continuing
debate on diversification versus functional separation of bank activities.
We thank John Doukas (the editor) and two anonymous referees for their insightful
comments and suggestions. We are also grateful to Dimitrios Andriosopoulos, Elena
Kalotychou, George Kavetsos and Giorgio Di Pietro for helpful comments on early drafts of
this paper. The paper was presented at the 2011 British Accounting and Finance Association
conference; the 2011 International Finance and Banking Society conference; the 2011
Financial Management AssociationEuropean conference and the 2013 Multinational Finance
Society conference. We would like to thank the session participants, in particular, Isil Erel,
Franco Fiordelisi, Philip Gharghori, Bjoern Hagendorff, Jens Hagendorff, Gerhard Kling,
Ornella Ricci, Ioannis Tsalavoutas, Francesco Vallascas and John O.S. Wilson for their
constructive feedback. All errors are our own. Correspondence: Panagiotis Dontis-Charitos.
European Financial Management, Vol. 22, No. 2, 2016, 235–275
doi: 10.1111/eufm.12061
© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Keywords: Banks, nonbank financial firms, financial conglomerates, diversification,
risk decomposition, determinants of risk
JEL classification: G21, G22, G32, G34
1. Introduction
This paper contributes to the on-going policy debate on bank diversification versus
functional separation by examining the risk profile of international banks following
acquisition of non-banking activities. It is little over a decade since the Financial Services
Modernization Act (FSMA) of 1999 revoked functional separation to allow US bank
holding companies (BHCs) to operate as financial conglomerates. Permitting the so-called
‘universal banking model’put US banks on equal footing with European banks, which
could operate as universal firms under the Second Banking Directive of 1989.
1
The
response of the financial services industry came in the form of a wave of consolidation,
often via mergers and acquisitions (M&A), through which financial institutions increased
the scale and scope of their activities.
2
Large and complex financial institutions were at the
core of the 2007–09 crisis. This has triggered a new debate on optimal bank size, focusing
either on capital surcharges for large banks (Basel III), or on the range of permissible
activities (Volker rule in the USA, and Vickers and Liikanen proposals in the UK and EU,
respectively).
This reaction has reignited the long-standing debate as to the costs and benefits of
diversification (Herring and Santomero, 1990; Boyd et al., 1998; Flannery, 1999;
Acharya et al., 2006; Herring and Carmassi, 2010; Elsas et al., 2010). At the public policy
level, concerns relate to extended monopoly powers of larger financial firms; conflicts of
interest between financial institutions and consumers; and the possibility that nonbank
financial firms could implicitly benefit from government subsidies targeted at banks via
‘too-big-to-fail’guarantees (Farhi and Tirole, 2012; Molyneux et al., 2014; Laeven et al.,
2014).
The perceived benefits of diversification include synergies from scope economies,
efficiency gains and profit-enhancing cross-selling opportunities (Houston et al., 2001;
Pilloff 1996; Vander Vennet, 2002). Furthermore, diversification may allow financial
1
The Financial Services Modernization Act (FSMA) of 1999 –also known as the Gramm-
Leach-Bliley Act (GLBA) –widened the range of permissible activities for banks. The
process of deregulation in US banking began before 1999 with the first step towards it thought
to have occurred in 1987 when the Federal Reserve allowed Citicorp, Bankers Trust and JP
Morgan to engage in limited underwriting and dealing in a set of securities. Several further
steps gradually eroded the restrictions of the Glass-Steagall Act. The Riegle-Neal Act of 1994
(Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act) let banks expand across states and engage
in geographical diversification. In Europe, the implementation of the Second Banking
Directive by all 15 member states was completed between 1991 and 1994.
2
In addition to financial deregulation, other forces encouraging consolidation in the financial
sector during the 1990s and early 2000s included improved information technology,
globalisation of financial and real markets, and heightened shareholder pressure for financial
performance. In Europe, the introduction of the euro accelerated the speed of financial market
integration and encouraged cross-border activity (Group of Ten, 2001).
© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
236 Barbara Casu, Panagiotis Dontis-Charitos, Sotiris Staikouras and Jonathan Williams
services firms to reduce insolvency risk due to the imperfect correlation of profits arising
from a broader set of financial activities. Critics, in contrast, perceive no diversification
benefits and instead voice concerns pertaining to the existence of diseconomies of scope
and greater inefficiencies at more diverse financial institutions (Laeven and Levine,
2007), which are deemed as more complex, difficult to regulate and harder to resolve
(Herring and Carmassi, 2010; Chow and Surti, 2011; Gambacorta and van Rixtel, 2013).
Indeed, plentiful evidence shows that substituting interest income with fee-based income
increases earnings volatility (DeYoung and Ronald, 2001; Stiroh 2004; Stiroh and
Rumble, 2006).
Nonetheless, substantial empirical evidence suggests benefits accrue to diversified
institutions relative to more specialised firms (Barth et al., 2000). Although much of the
evidence dates from the late 1990s and early 2000s, policymakers appear to endorse this
view. This paved the way for an unprecedented level of M&A activity in the financial
services industry, which has contributed to the emergence of a number of large and
increasingly complex financial institutions.
3
Following the 2007–09 crisis a growing number of academics and policymakers began
to debate if the size and permissible activities of financial institutions should be re-
constricted because of concerns over systemic risk. New legislation in the USA and
Europe now enforces a functional separation of impermissible investment banking
activities from commercial banking.
4
Whereas the permissible investment banking
activities may differ between the USA and across EU member states, and the mechanisms
to deliver separation range from institutional separation (in the USA) to subsidiarisation
(in the EU) to ring-fencing (in the UK), a common objective of structural bank regulation
is to protect the real economy and bank depositors from exogenous shocks and contagion
3
Most M&A activity during the 1990s in the financial sector involved banking firms.
Acquisitions of banking firms accounted for 60% (70%) of the total number (value) of
financial mergers (Group of Ten, 2001). The asset share of the five largest BHCs in the US
jumped from 21.2% to 48.0% between 1986 and 2006 (Stiroh, 2010). The evolution of the
mean ratio of non-interest income-to-total operating income, to proxy diversification, shows
that the BHCs increasingly diversified over time from 39.0% in 1986 to 53.2% in 2006.
Between these dates, the average BHC operated in more states (21 c.f. 5) and achieved greater
branch penetration (3,118 c.f. 463). Berger et al. (1999) and Berger et al. (2001) discuss the
consolidation process in the US and Europe.
4
The principle of the new legislation is to carve out predefined casino-like trading activities of
banks. A key difference between the US and European approaches is that the Volcker rule in
the US forbids the coexistence of predefined investment banking activities in different
subsidiaries within the same banking group, whereas the European and UK rules allow for
subsidiarisation of such activities in separately capitalised legal entities. In the US, the Dodd-
Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 implements the Volcker rule.
In the UK, the Financial Services (Banking Reform) Act of 2013 implements the Vickers
proposals. In January 2014, the European Commission published its proposal for a Volcker-
Vickers style reform, which deviates somewhat from the recommendations of the Liikanen
report of 2012. We should not expect agreement on the final version of the European
legislation until mid-2015, which infers an effective date of mid-2018. Mayer Brown (2014)
review the new European proposal and how it differs from Liikanen and UK and US rulings,
as well as overviewing recent French and German legislation.
© 2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Diversification, Size and Risk 237
To continue reading
Request your trial