Does trade credit really help relieving financial constraints?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12211
AuthorRoberto Guida,Valentina Meliciani,Stefania Cosci
Published date01 January 2020
Date01 January 2020
DOI: 10.1111/eufm.12211
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Does trade credit really help relieving financial
constraints?
Stefania Cosci
1
|
Roberto Guida
2
|
Valentina Meliciani
3
1
LUMSA University of Rome, Rome,
Italy
Email: s.cosci@lumsa.it
2
International University at Rome, Rome,
Italy
Email: r.guida@unint.eu
3
LUISS University of Rome, Rome, Italy
Email: vmeliciani@luiss.it
Abstract
The European Union introduced a directive aimed at
reducing trade credit due to its supposedly negative effect
on the European economy. This contrasts with the
redistribution view arguing that trade credit could facilitate
the financing of credit-constrained firms by more liquid
suppliers. But does trade credit mainly flow from relatively
unconstrained suppliers to more financially constrained
buyers? To answer this question, we look at the character-
istics of net borrowers with respect to net lenders and then
estimate the substitutability between trade and bank debt
separately for the two groups of firms. Overall, the results
show that, in Italy, efficient redistribution does not tend to
prevail in the trade credit market.
KEYWORDS
financial constraints, redistribution view, substitutability, trade credit
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G32, G21, D82
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The term trade credit refers to a variety of heterogeneous, unilaterally determined arrangements under
which individual suppliers of products or services allow their trade customers to defer payment for a
The authors are grateful to two anonymous referees and John Doukas (the Editor) for their helpful suggestions and
comments.
Eur Financ Manag. 2018;118. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm © 2019 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
|
1
d
i
p
r
U
M
M
p
B
p
m
c
s
w
n
i
a
1
i
o
v
W
t
o
N
c
W
C
E
(
F
c
b
b
p
a
e
l
r
o
p
1
2
H
C
198 © 2019 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm Eur Financ Manag. 2020;26:198–215.
EUROPEAN
r
a
1
designated period. Most firms, in both Europe and the United States, have significant amounts invested
in accounts receivable, as well as a substantial number of accounts payable, as a source of financing.
Even if most of the economic literature emphasizes the positive role of trade credit as a means of
providing funds to credit-constrained firms, there is evidence casting some doubts on its efficient
redistribution role. Prior studies (e.g., Atanasova, 2007; Carbo-Valverde, Rodriquez-Fernandez, &
Udell, 2016; Casey & OToole, 2014; Emery, 1984; Ferrando & Mulier, 2013; Garcia-Appendini &
Montoriol-Garriga, 2013; Huyghebaert, 2006; Jain, 2001; Love, Preve, & Sarria-Allende, 2007;
McGuinness, Hogan, & Powell, 2018; Petersen & Rajan, 1997) support the view that trade credit
provides a useful buffer for financially constrained firms. In contrast, some recent papers (Giannetti,
Burkart, & Ellingsen, 2011; Marotta, 2005; Murfin & Njoroge, 2015; Wilson & Summers, 2002)
predict that small firms with low bargaining power sell with low margins to large customers, supply
more trade credit, and even tolerate payment delays. This paper aims to shed light on whether trade
credit is always an effective way to foster the financing of small firms and to overcome the banking
system's shortcomings or whether it is mainly the consequence of power imbalance in the supply chain
whereby more powerful players impose long payment periods on smaller enterprises.
The function of intermediary of substitutionexerted by suppliers is supposedly facilitated by the
nature of the trade relation that underlies the financing. Compared to a classical financial intermediary,
intercompany relations make it possible for the seller to benefit from savings by collecting information
about firms, evaluating default risk, and evaluating products in case of bankruptcy (Petersen & Rajan,
1997). Trade credit demand is therefore justified by the need to limit the adverse effects of asymmetric
information, especially when banks do not adopt relationship lending technologies and do not produce
or use soft information about their borrowers. According to this view of trade credit (redistribution
view), firms with greater liquidity could help constrained firms finance their investment projects.
When credit flows from relatively unconstrained suppliers to more financially constrained buyers,
trade credit is characterized as an efficient financing arrangement but it is not uncommon to also
observe trade credit flowing from small, constrained suppliers to large corporations. Murfin and
Njoroge (2015) show that there are many trade credit relationships in which smaller, often credit-
constrained suppliers provide financing for their larger investment-grade buyers in the United States.
We could argue that, in this case, we have inefficient redistribution and, indeed, the European
Commission (EC) appears to be concerned with the negative consequences of late payment on the
European economy.
1
According to the EC, each year, thousands of small and medium-sized enterprises
(SMEs) go bankrupt waiting for their invoices to be paid. Directive 2011/7/EU (ENTR/172/PP/2012/
FC LOT 4) has implemented strict measures that are expected, when properly implemented by EU
countries, to contribute significantly to employment and growth and to improve the liquidity of
businesses by combating late payment in commercial transactions. The EC therefore believes there to
be issues in the conditions determined by suppliers under which they trust their customers to defer
payment.
According to EC (2015), three main factors explain the differences across countries, over time, and
across sectors regarding late payments: the prevailing business culture, deterioration of the general
economic climate, and power imbalance in the supply chain whereby more powerful actors impose
long payment periods on smaller suppliers (see also Marotta, 2005). However, the EC (2015, p. 30) also
recognizes the financing role of trade credit by stating: Armed with better information and
occasionally more influence over their trading partners, suppliers can actually be more effective sub-
prime lenders than the banking sector.
1
See http://ec.europa.eu/growth/smes/support/late-payment_en
2
|
ET AL.
HEATON 1151
199
COSCI ET AL
5.
EUROPEAN
|

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT