How Incomplete Contracts Foster Innovation in Inter‐Organizational Relationships

AuthorRegien Sumo,Arjan Weele,Wendy Valk,Geert Duysters
Date01 September 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/emre.12075
Published date01 September 2016
How Incomplete Contracts Foster Innovation
in Inter-Organizational Relationships
REGIEN SUMO,
1
WENDY VAN DER VALK,
2
ARJAN VAN WEELE
1
and GEERT DUYSTERS
2
1
Eindhoven University of Technology, Schoolof Industrial Engineering, Eindhoven, The Netherlands
2
Tilburg University, Tilburg School of Economics and Management, Tilburg, The Netherlands
Relative to relational governance, research into the use and effects of formal governance is scarce. Recent
contributions suggest that a specific type of contract that has intentionally been left incomplete, the performance-
based contract (PBC), fosters innovation. However, it is unknown how this effect occurs. To address this gap, we
draw on transactioncost economics and agency theoryto develop propositionson how PBCs affect innovation. PBCs
are characterized by low term specificity and rewards that are tied to performance. We propose that low term
specificity, that is, not stipulating how the focal firms partner should deliver the performance and which resources
to use, enhances the partners autonomy, which in turn fosters innovation. However, excessive low term specificity
inhibits innovation, since it may lead the partner to display opportunistic behavior. We furthermore propose that
performance-based pay incentivizes the partner to engage in innovation. This suggests that linking rewards to
performance attenuates the negative relationship between term specificity and innovation when the former is very
low. Finally, we propose that a morerisk-averse partner will engage in fewer innovative activities as such a partner
will be less sensitive to the pay-for-performance clause.
Keywords: Inter-organizational relationship; innovation; incomplete contract; transaction cost economics; agency
theory; term specificity; pay for performance; risk-averseness
Introduction
Firms often draw on both contractual and relational
governance to organize their inter-organizational
relationships (IORs) (Bradach, 1997; Mahapatra et al.,
2010), thereby taking advantage of their differential
impacts (Lindkvist, 1996). At the same time, the
performance implications of relational governance have
been studied much more extensively compared to the
impact of contractual governance (Sharma and Pillai,
2003; Vandaele et al., 2007). As contracts underlie
virtually any exchange relationship, it is important to
understand how the design of the contract may foster or
inhibit performance outcomes. Indeed, Schepker et al.,
(2014) emphasize the need to study the relationship
between contractsand relational outcomes.
This research specifically addresses how contracts affect
innovation, which is critical for firms to gain and sustain
competitive advantage (Brown and Eisenhardt, 1995;
Keupp et al., 2012; Hecker and Ganter; 2013; Hollen
et al., 2013). Since firms rely on externally developed as
well as internal knowledge to improve innovation and
create value (Chesbrough, 2003; Huston and Sakkab,
2006), external partners have become a critical source of
innovative solutions, ideas, and technologies (Van Echtelt
et al., 2008; Roy et al., 2004), not only for the focal firms
value proposition, but certainly also for their internal
processes/ daily operations. In our research, we focus on
innovation taking place within the context of a specific
IOR, more precisely in the contracted activities or
performance that a partner conducts for and in
collaboration with a specific focal firm. Within the context
of existing exchange relationships, partners may innovate
as part of their daily activities to incrementally improve or
more radically change the daily service delivery towards
the focal firm, with the aim to more efficiently achieve
performance targets such as quality and delivery time
(i.e., against lower costs). Thus, innovation as such is not
a contracted performance outcome, but a way to achieve
contracted performance/execute contracted activities more
efficiently and effectively. Both parties may benefit from
the partners innovations, for example, when innovation
results in a better service offering for the focal firm as well
as more efficient delivery of the transaction for the supplier.
IORs generally enhance (Faems et al., 2005; Goes and
Correspondence: Regien Sumo, Eindhoven University of Technology,
School of Industrial Engineering, PO box 513, CNT 0.16, 5600 MB
Eindhoven,The Netherlands, Tel: +3140 247 59 51. E-mail:
r.a.f.sumo@tue.nl
European Management Review, Vol. 13, 179192, (2016)
DOI: 10.1111/emre.12075
© 2016 European Academy of Management

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT