Idiosyncratic momentum and the cross‐section of stock returns: Further evidence

AuthorQi Lin
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12247
Published date01 June 2020
Date01 June 2020
Eur Financ Manag. 2020;26:579627. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm © 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
|
579
DOI: 10.1111/eufm.12247
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Idiosyncratic momentum and the crosssection
of stock returns: Further evidence
Qi Lin
School of Finance, Zhejiang University of
Finance and Economics, Hangzhou,
China
Correspondence
Qi Lin, School of Finance, Zhejiang
University of Finance and Economics,
18 Xueyuan Street, 310018 Hangzhou,
China.
Email: qlin_sf@zufe.edu.cn
Funding information
National Natural Science Foundation of
China, Grant/Award Number: 71703142
Abstract
In this article, we evaluate the profitability and
economic source of the predictive power of the
idiosyncratic momentum effect, by using five popular
asset pricing models to construct the idiosyncratic
momentum. We show that all five idiosyncratic
momentum strategies produce similar return predict-
ability and consistently outperform the conventional
momentum strategy in the crosssectional pricing of
equity portfolios and individual stocks. This positive
effect of idiosyncratic momentum on returns is
consistent with the investment capital asset pricing
model (CAPM). Further analysis reveals that the firm
level idiosyncratic momentum effect cannot extend to
the aggregate stock market.
KEYWORDS
asset pricing, idiosyncratic momentum, investment CAPM,
market return predictability
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G11; G12; G17
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Momentum, the notion that previous winners in the stock market continue to outperform
previous losers, is a pervasive anomaly in asset prices. Although momentum profits have been
EUROPEAN
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT
The author is grateful to the editor, John Doukas, and an anonymous referee for detailed and insightful comments and
suggestions. The author also gratefully acknowledges financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation
of China (Grant Number: 71703142).
widely documented in both US and international markets,
1
they exhibit significant exposures to
systematic risk factors (e.g., Grundy & Martin, 2001). Gutierrez and Prinsky (2007) find that a
momentum strategy that defines winners and losers based on firmspecific abnormal returns
significantly improves the performance of a conventional momentum strategy that ranks stocks
on raw returns.
2
Further, Blitz, Huij, and Martens (2011) show that a momentum strategy
constructed based on idiosyncratic returns estimated using the Fama and French (1993) three
factor model almost doubles riskadjusted profits compared with a strategy associated with
conventional momentum, due in large part to lower return variability. In their pioneering
study, the authors attribute the success of idiosyncratic momentum to the isolation of dynamic
exposures to Fama and French's (1993) three factors, as momentum loads positively (negatively)
on these factors when they have positive (negative) returns during the formation period of the
strategy. Blitz, Hanauer, and Vidojevic (2017), Chang, Ko, Nakano, and Rhee (2018), and Lin
(2019) document that the idiosyncratic momentum strategy continues to yield substantial
profits beyond the US market, including those markets where conventional momentum is
found to be ineffective.
3
Given the importance of the construction of the idiosyncratic returns, a natural question is
whether the choice of asset pricing models to estimate idiosyncratic returns affects the
profitability of the idiosyncratic momentum. In this study, we first reevaluate the relation
between idiosyncratic momentum and crosssectional stock returns and explore whether
idiosyncratic momentum has greater predictive power than conventional momentum. We
extend Blitz et al.'s (2011) approach and construct the idiosyncratic momentum measures
(iMOM) by estimating idiosyncratic returns from five popular asset pricing models: the capital
asset pricing model of Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) (CAPM); the threefactor model of
Fama and French (1993) (FF3); the fourfactor model in Carhart (1997) that augments FF3 with
a momentum factor (C4); the fivefactor model of Fama and French (2015) (FF5); and the
q
factor model of Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2015) (Q4). We find three primary results.
First, although the conventional momentum strategy produces a slightly greater, yet
insignificant, winnerminusloser spread return on average than strategies sorted by
idiosyncratic momentum, including the strategy formed on
i
MOMFF3, idiosyncratic momentum
strategies have significantly lower volatilities and yield significantly greater Sharpe ratios than
the conventional momentum strategy. Second, we provide new evidence that the performance
of the idiosyncratic momentum strategies is insensitive to the asset pricing models used to
construct them. For all five idiosyncratic momentum winnerminusloser portfolios, the average
excess returns and alphas are consistently positive and the associated
t
statistics pass the higher
hurdle rate of three, as suggested by Harvey, Liu, and Zhu (2016), which indicates that the
idiosyncratic momentum effect is unlikely to be due to chance or data snooping. The
meanvariance spanning test of Kan and Zhou (2012) also confirms that idiosyncratic
momentum is not simply a manifestation of conventional momentum and wellknown risk
factors. More importantly, all three tests from Andrews (1991), Andrews and Monahan (1992),
and Ledoit and Wolf (2008) cannot reject the null that there is no difference in Sharpe ratios
between idiosyncratic momentum spread portfolios. Third, model Q4 outperforms the
competing models in capturing different versions of iMOM, resulting in the smallest alphas,
1
See, for example, Jegadeesh and Titman (1993, 2001), Rouwenhorst (1998), Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999), Johnson (2002), Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2003),
Chui, Titman, and Wei (2010), Fama and French (2012), Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen (2013), Goyal and Wahal (2015), and Li (2017).
2
Throughout the article, we refer to Jegadeesh and Titman's (1993) momentum strategy as conventional momentum strategy.
3
Blitz et al. (2011) also refer to idiosyncratic momentum as residual momentum.
580
|
EUROPEAN
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT
LIN
information ratios, and aggregate pricing errors and yielding the highest
p
values in the
Gibbons, Ross, and Shanken (1989) test. These findings echo Hou et al. (2015, 2017), who show
that model Q4 outperforms models FF3 and FF5 in accommodating a wide range of anomalies
at the portfolio level. We also find that our results are insensitive to the scalingof
idiosyncratic momentum.
Given the similar return predictability among iMOM and the strong power of idiosyncratic
momentum in predicting the crosssection of stock returns, we further investigate several
potential explanations for the economic source of its predictability.
The similar performance among idiosyncratic momentum strategies appears to be striking,
as Blitz et al. (2011) argue that the success of idiosyncratic momentum is due to the isolation of
dynamic factor exposures. While we find consistent evidence that conventional momentum has
substantial timevarying exposures not only to the market factor but also to the size and value
factors, as in Blitz et al. (2011), the similar profitability across idiosyncratic momentum
strategies suggests that hedging out timevarying exposures to the latter two factors cannot
improve the strategy's performance significantly compared with a strategy that isolates only the
timevarying exposure to the market factor. In addition, we find that conventional momentum
exhibits timevarying exposures to factors other than those in the Fama and French (1993)
model. To evaluate the dynamic risk explanation deeply, we further examine the role of time
varying factor exposures in the profitability of idiosyncratic momentum strategies by using
conditional asset pricing models in the spirit of Grundy and Martin (2001), which enables us to
neutralize the dynamicfactor exposures directly in all models. Idiosyncratic momentum
strategies constructed using conditional models yield average excess returns that are only
5080% as high as those constructed using Blitz et al.'s (2011) approach. More surprisingly,
except for the strategy constructed using the conditional CAPM, the studentized timeseries
bootstrap test of Ledoit and Wolf (2008) indicates that none of these strategies yields greater
Sharpe ratios than the conventional momentum strategy, even at the 10% significance level.
Taken together, our results suggest that the superior performance of idiosyncratic momentum
seems not to be driven by the isolation of dynamic factor risk.
Another potential explanation of the idiosyncratic momentum effect is that it captures
common sources of mispricing, such as marketwide investor sentiment. Miller (1977) argues
that the presence of shortsale constraints implies that overpricing is more likely than
underpricing, as the former is more difficult to eliminate due to costly shorting. Stambaugh, Yu,
and Yuan (2012) further show that the combination of Miller's (1977) argument about the effect
of shortsale impediments and marketwide sentiment suggests that anomalies should be
stronger during periods of high sentiment, to the extent that the anomalies reflect mispricing.
However, we find that idiosyncratic momentum spread returns do not display such patterns
and that their average excess returns and alphas are indistinguishable from zero between high
and lowsentiment periods, particularly after controlling for wellknown risk factors. Moreover,
there is no significant relation between sentiment and average excess returns and alphas on the
long legs, which appears to be consistent with the prediction of Stambaugh et al. (2012).
However, we also find no significantly lower average excess returns and alphas on the short legs
following high sentiment than following low sentiment. Hence, the idiosyncratic momentum is
unrelated to marketwide investor sentiment.
To gain further insight into the economic source of the idiosyncratic momentum effect
documented in this article, we then explore whether this effect is consistent with the investment
CAPM, which is built on the neoclassical
q
theory of investment (Cochrane, 1991; Liu, Whited, &
Zhang, 2009; Zhang, 2017). George, Hwang, and Li (2018) argue that the test of the investment
LIN EUROPEAN
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT
|
581

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT