Lottery preferences and the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle

Date01 June 2019
Published date01 June 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12178
655Eur Financ Manag. 2019;25:655–683. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm © 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
DOI: 10.1111/eufm.12178
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Lottery preferences and the idiosyncratic volatility
puzzle
Doina C. Chichernea
1
|
Haimanot Kassa
2,3
|
Steve L. Slezak
4
1
Reiman School of Finance, Daniels
College of Business, University of
Denver, Denver, Colorado
Email: doina.chichernea@du.edu
2
Department of Finance, Farmer School
of Business, Miami University, Oxford,
Ohio
Email: kassah@miamioh.edu
3
US Securities and Exchange
Commission, Washington, District of
Columbia
4
Department of Finance and Real Estate,
Lindner College of Business, University
of Cincinnati, Cincinnati, Ohio
Email: steve.slezak@uc.edu
Abstract
We investigate the empirical implications of investors
heterogeneous preferences for skewness with respect to the
idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL) puzzle, that is, the negative
correlation between IVOL and mean returns. We show that
the IVOL puzzle is stronger: (1) within stocks held
primarily by agents with a preference for lottery-like
payoffs; and (2) during economic downturns, when the
demand for lottery-like payoffs is high. These results
support recent theories that suggest lottery preferences
could be a significant source of the IVOL puzzle.
KEYWORDS
economic conditions, idiosyncratic volatility, lottery preferences,
skewness
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G11,G12
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The negative empirical relation between idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL) and subsequent stock returns
has been considered a puzzle since it was first documented by Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006).
We are thankful for the helpful comments and suggestions from an anonymous referee, the editor (John Doukas), Tom
Boulton, Alexander Borisov, Kelly Brunarski, Colin Campbell, Michael Ferguson, Mark Griffiths, Hui Guo, Yvette
Harman, Tyler Henery, Bochen Li, David Manzler, Terry Nixon, Alex Petkevich, Chen Xue, Steve Wyatt, and Kim Yong.
We benefited from discussions with seminar participants at Miami University, the University of Cincinnati, the Eastern
Finance Association, the Midwest Finance Association, and the Southwestern Finance Association. We are responsible for
any errors. The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) disclaims responsibility for any private publication or
statement of any SEC employee or Commissioner. This paper expresses the authorsviews and does not necessarily reflect
those of the Commission, the Commissioners, or other members of the staff.
2
|
CHICHERNEA ET AL.
C
656
The subsequent literature suggests a link between the so-called IVOL puzzle and investor preferences
for lottery-like features (i.e., skewness; see Bali, Cakici, & Whitelaw, 2011; Boyer, Mitton, & Vorkink,
2010). If so, then the IVOL puzzle should be more pronounced within the universe of stocks held by
agents who prefer lottery-like payoffs. Further, since the literature (e.g., Kumar, 2009) shows that the
demand for lottery-like characteristics varies countercyclically over time, the IVOL puzzle should also
be more pronounced during economic downturns, when the demand for lottery-like features increases.
Our paper provides evidence that supports both hypotheses.
A negative relation between positive skewness and subsequent returns is implied by heterogeneous
investorspreferences for skewness. In models in which the mean and variance are sufficient to
characterize either security returns or investorspreferences (e.g., the capital asset pricing model or
CAPM), all investors optimally hold meanvariance-efficient portfolios. If, in addition to caring about
mean and variance, some investors also derive utility from positive skewness, then these investors will,
at prices implied by meanvariance efficiency, create excess demand for securities with positive
skewness. This has two implications: (1) the prices of lottery-like assets will be bid up to clear the
market, resulting in lower subsequent returns relative to securities without lottery-like features; and
(2) since the market-clearing price is a compromise between the valuations of each type of investor,
prices are bid up in equilibrium such that meanvariance investors hold proportionally less and mean
varianceskewness investors hold proportionally more lottery-like securities. A third implication
concerns the magnitudes of these effects. The greater the skewness benefit a security offers, the greater
the reduction in the expected return and the greater the decrease in expected return, the greater the
disparity between the proportional holdings of lottery-like securities between meanvariance and
meanvarianceskewness investors.
While it is intuitive that (at least some) investors might have a preference for positive skewness, it is
not obvious why investors would have a preference for IVOL; thus, the above argument for a negative
equilibrium relation between skewness and future returns does not apply for IVOL. However, the
literature highlights a couple of reasons why IVOL and skewness could be connected empirically. First,
it is possible that IVOL is an inherent feature of firms that have lottery-type returns. The literature
presents at least two conceptual reasons for such a connection: (1) IVOL is positively related to
corporate growth options, which induce greater skewness in returns (Andrés-Alonso, Azofra-
Palenzuela, & La Fuente-Herrero, 2006; Cao, Simin, & Zhao, 2008); and (2) a higher IVOL is related to
technological revolutions, which also induce greater skewness in returns, since a few winners emerge
and other firms fail (Jovanovic & MacDonald, 1994; Pástor & Veronesi, 2009). Second, the IVOL
measures used in the literature are typically based on models in which investors are well diversified and
hold portfolios on a meanvariance frontier (e.g., multifactor CAPM), in which there is no (negative)
risk premium for skewness. Such models will misspecify expected returns for lottery-like securities,
which will likely result in upwardly biased estimates of the true IVOL for these securities. Thus,
securities with greater skewness will have higher estimated IVOL. Finally, stocks with exceptionally
high volatility are likely to have positive skewness by default, given the limited liability nature of
equity (Conine & Tamarkin, 1981).
Regardless of the exact channel, if there is a connection between IVOL and lottery-like features,
then perhaps the IVOL puzzle is not symptomatic of a puzzle at all, but is simply a proxy for the rational
pricing of skewness instead.
1
To differentiate, it would be nice to be able to pit the alternative
1
This is also consistent with a behavioral bias. For example, Barberis and Huang (2008) argue that, under cumulative
prospect theory, investors overweight small chances of large gains (and hence have lottery preferences). Therefore, such
investors prefer (and bid up) positively skewed stocks, causing them to be overpriced and earn low subsequent returns.
i
u
s
i
r
i
(
i
r
i
m
n
S
a
p
m
t
o
s
d
t
i
(
p
p
o
o
i
a
b
s
s
p
(
h
2
e
r
s
I
i
3
t

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT