Getting it right or getting it cursed: Auction prices in a residential real estate bubble

Published date01 November 2019
Date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12200
DOI: 10.1111/eufm.12200
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Getting it right or getting it cursed: Auction prices
in a residential real estate bubble
Clare Branigan
|
Cal Muckley
|
Paul Ryan
UCD College of Business, University
College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, Ireland
Emails: clare.branigan@ucd.ie;
cal.muckley@ucd.ie; paul.ryan@ucd.ie
Funding information
Science Foundation Ireland, Grant number:
16/SPP/3347
Abstract
This is the first study to test for a winner's curse in a bubble
market. Our hand-collected sample comprises the sequence
of bids and the experience of the winning bidder at Irish
residential real estate auctions, prior to the collapse of the
bubble. Portfolios of practitioner- and hedonic pricing model-
selected self-similar properties provide benchmark property
price estimates. We show neither real estate investors nor
owner occupiers shade auction bids to avoid the winner's
curse and both raise bids in line with competition. Winning
investor bidders pay more for properties, ride the wave of a
property bubble, and potentially exacerbate it.
KEYWORDS
bubbles, owner occupier, professional investor, residential real estate,
winner's curse
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G00, G01, G02, G10, R31
1
|
INTRODUCTION
This is the first study to test for a winner's curse in an auction setting in a bubble market. We examine, in
agrowth-of-bubble setting, the formulation of bidding strategies of winning bidders in real estate
The authors thank John Doukas (the Editor), two anonymous referees, Utpal Bhattacharya, Réne Stulz, and Richard Taffler
for their insightful comments. This paper has also benefited from comments made by participants at the European Real
Estate Society Annual Conference in Bucharest in June 2014, the Behavioural Finance Working Group Annual Conference
in Queen Mary College, University of London, June 2014, and the Chartered Financial Analysts (CFA) Program Partners
Conference in the University of Southern California in July 2014. Cal Muckley would like to acknowledge the financial
support of Science Foundation Ireland under Grant Number 16/SPP/3347. The usual disclaimer applies.
Eur Financ Manag. 2018;1–29. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm © 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
|
1
1121Eur Financ Manag. 2019;25:1121–1149. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/eufm © 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
auctions. That momentum (Case & Shiller, 1988), mean reversion (Cutler, Poterba, & Summers,
1991), and excess variance relative to fundamentals (Glaeser, Gyourko, Morales, & Nathanson, 2014)
characterize metropolitan area real estate housing prices is well known. And that, there are far-reaching
and material implications of a convulsive real estate market for the real economy (Brocker & Hanes,
2014), via firm-level investment (Gan, 2007) and the financial sector (Gorton & Metrick, 2012), are a
matter of major concern. There is, however, scant field evidence, in this critically important growth-of-
bubble market phase, in regard to the factors which persuade these real estate bidders to bid high. We
aim, by availing of a unique, hand-collected and insightful data set of Dublin residential real estate
English open-bid outcry auctions, to characterize winning bidder strategies in this market.
A winner's curse occurs in auctions when a successful bidder finds that she has paid too much for an
item due to suboptimal trading behavior. As the range of auctioned asset value estimates and bids
increases (i.e., in line with uncertainty in the auctioned asset and the number of bidders) across auction
participants, the winning bidder will overestimate the true value (i.e., the average bid) of the auctioned
asset, overbid, and, hence, experience the winner's curse. To mitigate the winner's curse, in a first price
sealed-bid common value auction, optimal (rational) trading behavior implies bids which vary
inversely (so-called bid shading) with the uncertainty in the value of the asset under auction (Bazerman
& Samuelson, 1983) and with the level of competition between the bidders (Kagel & Levin, 1986).
Exposure to the winner's curse is, however, attenuated in English open-bid outcry auctions (Levin,
Kagel, & Richard, 1996): open-bidding, especially by a large number of bidders, reduces uncertainty
by imparting information which the bidders can use to update their estimates of value. This reduction in
uncertainty, in the auctioned asset, markedly diminishes the likelihood of a winner's curse. A related
behavioral argument, alluded to in Cramton (1998), suggests that, in these ascending bid auctions,
winning bids can be expected to vary positively in association with competition due to the ‘comfort
afforded’ to the bidder that it is not necessary, to win, to overbid by more than one bid increment.
Auctioned asset price uncertainty implies, in the same vein, that others can still be expected to pay
more, prior to the resolution of the auction, than the subsequent bid and that this can be reassuring for
the marginal bidder – when formulating, what turns out to be, the winning bid. As a result, in English
open-bid outcry auctions, we expect a positive relation between the winning bid prices and competition
and auctioned asset price uncertainty, to be a characterizing feature of winning bidder strategies.
The issue of whether there is a winner's curse prevalent in auction markets is contentious. While
Davis and Holt (1993) and Kagel and Levin (2002) use laboratory experiments which show bidders
falling victim to the winner's curse, empirical tests in field settings report both no evidence of a winner's
curse (Boone & Mulherin, 2008; Hendricks & Porter, 1987; Thiel, 1988) and, in a variety of auction
settings, evidence of this phenomenon (Roll, 1986; Veraiya, 1988). In the corporate takeover market,
1
for instance, Roll (1986) and Veraiya (1988) find evidence of overconfident managers falling prey to
the winner's curse, while Boone and Mulherin (2008) find, to the contrary, that a competitive market
holds. New findings, provided by laboratory experiments on the winner's curse, can prove insightful.
Though the design of these tests can induce biases (Hansen & Lott, 1991) and they can neglect
institutional features which aim to mitigate the winner's curse (Dyer & Kagel, 1996). The chief
concern, as indicated by Thiel (1988), in respect to empirical field studies of a winner's curse, is the
difficulty in accurately inferring a benchmark value of reference for the auctioned item.
The sole extant study of a winner's curse in a real estate setting, Tse, Pretorius, and Chau (2011),
reports bid shading, in respect to auctioned asset price uncertainty. It is posited that this bid shading, by
1
The firm acquisition process can be viewed as similar to an English open out-cry auction (e.g., Fishman, 1988; Ravid &
Spiegel, 1999).
2
|
BRANIGAN
ET AL.
p
o
n
c
w
a
n
b
b
p
p
a
M
p
u
e
i
u
m
b
u
t
d
e
e
p
t
u
c
(
r
t
t
t
o
a
r
a
h
o
c
o
i
b
r
B
H
1152
|
EUROPEAN
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT
HEATON
1122
B
BRANIGAN
ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT