Hard and Soft Law in the Construction of Social Europe: the Role of the Open Method of Co‐ordination

Published date01 May 2005
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0386.2005.00263.x
AuthorLouise G. Trubek,David M. Trubek
Date01 May 2005
Hard and Soft Law in the Construction of
Social Europe: the Role of the Open
Method of Co-ordination
David M. Trubek and Louise G. Trubek*
Abstract: The debate over the Open Method of Co-ordination has reopened discussion of
the role of ‘soft law’ in the process of European integration. This paper outlines the debate
over the relative value of hard and soft law in EU social policy, explores the operation of
non-binding objectives and guidelines in the European Employment Strategy, suggests a
number of reasons why ‘soft law’ might be effective in this area, and explores the possi-
bility for productive combination of hard and soft law measures.
I Introduction
The issue of the contribution of ‘soft law’ to the construction of Europe has remerged
in new form. Writing a decade ago, Francis Snyder noted that rules of conduct that
may have no legally binding force may nevertheless have practical effects for European
integration.1In recent years,a new formally non-binding but potentially important nor-
mative system has emerged through the Open Method of Co-ordination (OMC). The
OMC employs non-binding objectives and guidelines to bring about change in social
policy and other areas.
The OMC originated with the European Employment Strategy (EES) and has since
been applied to other areas, such as social inclusion and pensions. In the short period
since its formal inception at the Lisbon Summit, the OMC has generated a great deal
of discussion and debate. Much of the controversy concerns the respective merits of
‘hard’ and ‘soft’ law in the construction of Social Europe.2
European Law Journal, Vol.11, No. 3, May 2005, pp. 343–364.
© Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK
and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA
*Governance Project, Center for World Affairs and the Global Economy, European Union Center, and
Law School, University of Wisconsin-Madison.
1Snyder, ‘Soft Law and Institutional Practice in the European Community’, in S. Martin (ed.), The Con-
struction of Europe (Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1994), 198.
2Some prefer to refer to the OMC as ‘soft governance’ rather than soft law, to distinguish the OMC from
situations in which non-binding forms of guidance are rendered binding by being used to interpret legal
obligations, and to indicate that the process has many elements beyond the objectives and guidelines.
K. Jacobsson, ‘Between Deliberation and Discipline: Soft Governance in EU Employment Policy’, in
U. Morth (ed.), Soft Law in Governance and Regulation: An Interdisciplinary Analysis (Edward Edgar,
forthcoming).
Both those who favour the OMC as a mode of governance and those who question
its desirability compare the OMC,implicitly or explicitly, with the Community Method.
The Community Method is thought of as ‘hard law’ because it creates uniform rules
that Member States must adopt, provides sanctions if they fail to do so, and allows
challenges for non-compliance to be brought in court. In contrast, the OMC, which
has general and open-ended guidelines rather than rules, provides no formal sanctions
for Member States that do not follow the guidelines, and is not justiciable, is thought
of as ‘soft law’. Proponents of the OMC argue that it can be effective despite—or even
because of—its open-ended, non-binding, non-justiciable qualities. Opponents ques-
tion that conclusion. They not only argue that the OMC cannot do what is needed to
construct Social Europe and that ‘hard law’ is essential, but also contend that use of
the OMC could undermine efforts to build the hard law they think will be needed.
On close analysis, this debate turns on a number of highly contested issues. These
include the relative effectiveness of the Community Method and the OMC, the goals
for Social Europe, and the nature of the obstacles to reaching those goals. When pro-
ponents of the OMC contend that it is better suited than the Community Method for
certain tasks, they are not only making assumptions about the nature of the tasks and
the capabilities of the open method; they are also implicitly or explicitly making
assumptions about the capabilities of the Community Method. Similarly, when oppo-
nents of the OMC argue that its use should be limited in order to prevent erosion of
the acquis or block future efforts to use hard law, they do so because of beliefs both
about the OMC and the Community Method, as well as assumptions concerning the
proper role of the EU in social policy.
To a large degree, the people in this debate seem to be talking past each other. The
policy discussion should be about the goals for Social Europe and the tasks needed to
reach those goals. The institutional debate should be about the relative capacities of
different modes to handle specific certain governance tasks, and discussion should focus
on evidence relating to those capacities. Yet one often sees people on both sides making
a priori assumptions about goals, and unsupported assertions about the superior capac-
ity of the mode they favour,with little reference to data or alternative views. As a result,
issues sometimes get framed in an either/or fashion: either one should only use soft law,
or one should only employ hard law. Such framing not only cuts off much-needed
empirical inquiry into relative capacity; it also deters exploration of hybrid (hard and
soft) governance modes, and possible synergies between binding and non-binding
mechanisms.
The debate over hard and soft law has recently come to a head. The issue took on
special importance because it was injected into the discussion of the future Constitu-
tion of the European Union, where there has been substantial dialogue concerning the
OMC. The debates in the European Constitutional Convention confirmed what was
already apparent in the literature: the debate is not just about governance modes; it is
also about policy options, with many who favour hard law also holding a very differ-
ent policy position from the proponents of softer methods.
The goal of this paper is not to resolve these debates, but to help clarify the issues,
and identify questions for further work. We want to unpack the arguments on both
sides, identify contestable assumptions, and expose false dichotomies. While we favour
continued use of ‘soft law’ as well as hard/soft hybrids, we recognise that further work
on relative capacities and their relationship to policy goals must be done before any
final conclusions are reached.
European Law Journal Volume 11
344 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT