Law and the Financial Crisis: Searching for Europe's New Gold Standard

Date01 March 2014
Published date01 March 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eulj.12032
AuthorDaniel Wilsher
Law and the Financial Crisis: Searching
for Europe’s New Gold Standard
Daniel Wilsher*
Abstract: The role of law in the governance of the Eurozone confronts divergent eco-
nomic and political perspectives which are reminiscent of the gold standard era. The
Maastricht model sought to use to law to create a sound currency. In practice, fixed
exchange rates caused large trade imbalances and risky cross-border investments result-
ing in a Eurozone-wide crisis of first private, and then later, public insolvency. In the face
of continued political unwillingness to either pool fiscal resources or impose massive
austerity and structural reform, the European Central Bank ECB has been forced to
become lender of last resort to sovereigns to maintain the single currency. Ordo-liberal
critics argue that the ECB has created a transfer union in breach of the Maastricht
agreement. Keynesians, by contrast, argue that, just as under the gold standard, using
‘constitutionalised’ austerity to rebalance trade is neither just nor credible. The Euro-
zone’s reliance on law and markets above developed political institutions has failed, but
no democratically legitimate process has replaced it.
I Introduction—The Role of Law in the Economics of the Eurozone
‘[T]he European Union is a community of law, subscribed to by the Member States in
which pacta sunt servanda. This refers to all the pacts, starting from fiscal discipline in
the Member States to the commitment of the Member States to pay their debts . . .
The euro . . . is about respect for the law.’1
The role of law in the economic crisis engulfing Europe is ambiguous. Within
European scholarship, law is generally portrayed as having been a crucial driver
towards integration. The EU eventually established a quasi-constitutional legal frame-
work that removed much interstate political bargaining from economic life to be
replaced by the rule of law and the ‘neutrality’ of the market. The crowning legal
achievement, the single currency, was supposed to operate in a similar manner: legal
rules mandated both fiscal discipline and an independent central bank to control
* Senior Lecturer in Law, City Law School, City University, London, UK.
1Intervention by Lorenzo Bini Smaghi, Deputy-President, European Central Bank, ECON Committee
Hearing on ‘Improving the economic governance and stability framework of the Union, in particular in
the euro area,’ Brussels, 15 September 2010. This reflects the standard ‘creditor’ view with its implica-
tion that a financial crisis is the responsibility of delinquent debtors who must honour their obligations,
rather than the result of a system in which creditor/surplus countries are symbiotically dependent on
debtors for generating their continuing surpluses. For a discussion of this process, see J. Williamson,
‘Getting Surplus Countries to Adjust’, (2011) Peterson Institute for International Economics, Policy
Brief 11-01.
bs_bs_banner
European Law Journal, Vol. 20, No. 2, March 2014, pp. 241–283.
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd., 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK
and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA
inflation. The establishment of a stable currency by law would enable free markets to
deliver growth and prosperity. The EU, unable or unwilling to engage in new forms
of political life, put its faith, once again, in law and economics. The crisis has revealed
that a single currency without deeper forms of cooperation, whilst possible as a matter
of economic theory and legal design, has proved unstable in practice.
During the crisis, the proper limits of the established legal framework have become
a source of contention. Given the cataclysmic implications of failure, it is surprising,
even surreal, how often the focus has been upon the issue of whether the Eurozone
institutions or its Members are acting unlawfully.2The EU has resembled a firefighter
who, at the scene of a blaze threatening to engulf a neighbourhood, worries she
cannot extract water from a nearby house without the owner’s permission. The
Maastricht treaty has thus appeared at times to be a suicide pact. In reality, of course,
arguments about the proper scope of the Eurozone’s legal powers also reflect disputes
about both the causes of the crisis and distributing the costs of resolving it. More
fundamentally, they have come to reveal deeper questions about the nature of fiat
money and its link to sovereign democratic government. The question of what the EU
may legally do has become entangled with that of what it should do.
This article explores the role of law in the crisis and its relationship to the under-
lying economic and political debates. It begins by noting that the Eurozone’s con-
tinuing obsession with the enforcement of fiscal rules fails to address a more critical
issue: the regulation of trade and financial imbalances that have posed problems for
global economic governance ever since the end of the classical gold standard era. The
article then explores the legal design of the single currency and its operation prior to
the crisis. The next section considers the response of the EU institutions to the crisis,
with a particular focus upon the controversial role of the European Central Bank
(ECB). The article then addresses the legal, political and economic problems posed by
the steps followed so far.
At least amongst economists, it is generally agreed now that the Maastricht struc-
ture allowed unsustainable private imbalances to develop.3Economic evidence shows
that open and under-regulated capital markets in Europe mirrored wider trends
towards excessive private sector risk taking. These capital flows were the necessary
counterparts to huge trade surpluses amassed by Northern European states.4Banks in
the surplus countries engaged in a kind of vendor finance as cross-border lending
mushroomed. These capital flows reversed suddenly in 2008–2010 leading to banking
and, ultimately, fiscal crises. The banking sector’s travails were worsened because
Maastricht had not created a banking union to protect confidence in weaker
economies’ banking systems. With the flight to safety, a sovereign debt panic was
2See M. Ruffert, ‘The European Debt Crisis and European Union Law’, (2011) 48 CML Review
1777–1806 for an analysis which reveals the tension between law and resolving the crisis. He criticises
the strategy adopted to tackle the crisis concluding that there ‘are good reasons to submit that this
policy is in breach of important provision of the TFEU’ (785) arguing that this undermines the principle
that ‘[t]the European Union is a Union based on the rule of law, not of power (claimed by whomsoever),
and this must also hold in times of distress.’ At the same time, he offers no plausible alternative
economic solutions, either within or without the legal framework of Maastricht, to the crisis that faced
the Eurozone in 2010–2012. This suggests that Maastricht was indeed a constitutional ‘suicide pact.’
3N. Holinski, C. Kool and J. Muysken, ‘Persistent Macroeconomic Imbalances in the Euro Area: Causes
and Consequences’, (2012) 94(1) Fed Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 1.
4See S. Barnes, ‘Resolving and Avoiding Unsustainable Imbalances in the Euro Area’, (2010) OECD
Economics Department Working Papers, No.827.
European Law Journal Volume 20
242 © 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
allowed to spread across Europe in 2010–2011. Because of the narrow monetary
rather than political—basis of the Maastricht framework, countries in recession could
not benefit from automatic federal-level spending programmes or shared debt issu-
ance. Direct loans met political resistance and required legal changes to the Treaty.
However, without any Treaty amendment, massive amounts of liquidity have been
marshalled through the ECB and the wider European System of Central Banks
(ESCB).5Initially, this aimed to stabilise the banking system but latterly has served to
keep sovereigns solvent in the face of market fears of devaluation and default.
In interpreting these events, there is a powerful strand of German economic think-
ing, derived from the Hayekian and ordo-liberal schools, that argues that law is
critical to resolving the crisis, in particular, by reaffirming the rules on fiscal and
monetary discipline.6Failure by Member States, and latterly the ECB, to adhere to
these rules is viewed as legally illegitimate, a political breach of the ‘spirit’ of the
Maastricht treaty and, above all, economically dangerous.7Austerity and tight,
market-led, credit conditions will restore balance and ensure that the cost of bad
lending and investment decisions are not borne by taxpayers.8Liberal economists now
argue that the vast liquidity provided through the ESCB both risks creating an
illegitimate transfer union and impedes the process of localised deflation necessary to
restore competitiveness. By contrast, Keynesians argue that since trade surpluses and
misplaced private investment (rather than fiscal indiscipline) caused the crisis, it is
misguided to simply reaffirm budgetary law. Levels of public and private debt must be
reduced by deliberate policy choices—either inflation or debt restructuring—not left to
markets forces. To impose a one-sided adjustment on debtors by ‘internal devalua-
tion’ at a time of generally depressed conditions is politically and economically
unlikely to succeed.
Creditor Member State governments have been unwilling, as yet, to recommit fully
to a rules-based, market-led order. Whilst reaffirming the rules on fiscal discipline,
they remain fearful of the damage default or exit would do to their own economies.
The direct economics costs would include diminution in the value of their assets held
in the periphery and the recapitalisation costs of their banks.9Indirect costs would be
5The sources of direct support include bilateral aid and pledges to the EFSM, EFSF and the ESM which
when combined could reach 800 billion. These have so far been drawn upon by Ireland, Portugal,
Greece and, most recently, Spain. More significant are the indirect funds from the ECB which include
1.2 trillion in LTRO funds granted to private banks, 200 billion in Securities Markets Program funds
paid out for sovereign bonds, TARGET2 account credits of around 900 billion granted to national
central banks in the periphery and Emergency Liquidity Assistance of 240 billion made by national
central banks to their private banks. It is important to note that some of these amounts involve
‘double-counting’ as the sovereign TARGET2 claims are the public accounting entry reflecting ECSB
loans to private banks.
6For a good overview of the development and basis of ordo-liberal thought and see D. Gerber, Law and
Competition in Twentieth Century Europe: Protecting Prometheus (Oxford University Press, 1998), Ch.7.
7For a detailed discussion of the influence of German ordo-liberalism upon the interpretation of the
European treaties see W. Sauter, ‘The Economic Constitution of the European Union’, (1998) 4
Columbia Journal of European Law 27 at 43–56.
8For a good range of influential German economists see the debate in the papers collected in the CESifo
Forum 2012. Accessible at http://www.cesifo-group.de/portal/page/portal/ifoHome/b-publ/b2journal/
30publforum/_PUBLFORUM12
9J. Bibow, ‘The Euro Debt Crisis and Germany’s Euro Trilemma’, (2012) Levy Economics Institute
Working Paper No.721 who shows that Germany’s net foreign asset position grew from 0 to over 40%
GDP during the course of the single currency. Of this, she held assets worth 7.5% GDP in Spain, 5%
GDP in Ireland and 3% in Italy in 2010. The more recent shrinkage in the private sector asset portfolio
March 2014 Law—Eurozone—Maastricht Settlement—ECB
243
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT