New Entrant or Incumbent Advantage in Light of Regulatory Change: A Multiple Case Study of the Swedish Life Insurance Industry

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/emre.12345
Published date01 March 2020
Date01 March 2020
New Entrant or Incumbent Advantage in
Light of Regulatory Change: A Multiple Case
Study of the Swedish Life Insurance Industry
MARTIN SKÖLD,
1
ÅKE FREIJ
2
and JOHAN FRISHAMMAR
3,1
1
Stockholm School of Economics, House of Innovation & Scania Research Center, 113 83, Stockholm, Sweden
2
Stockholm School of Economics, House of Innovation, 113 83, Stockholm, Sweden
3
Entrepreneurship and Innovation, Luleå University ofTechnology, SE-971 87, Luleå
When an industryis disrupted, the predominantview is that new entrants benefit at the expenseof incumbents, who
are pictured as slow-moving, inert, and incapable to change. Based on a longitudinal multiple case study with data
over a 15-year period, we challenge this view. By studying the action responses of three incumbent firms and three
new entrants to a major regulatory change in the life insurance industry, we find that both incumbents and new
entrants can succeed if complementary assets are correctly managed. In particular, firms need to acquire and refine
certain key assets needed for exploiting new business opportunities and, subsequently, need to enhance the value of
their complementary assets by transforming them from generic to specialized and on to co-specialized stages. These
findings have theoretical implications for the literature on strategy and innovation management. In addition, we
outline important managerial implications to transform complementary assets to stages with higher value.
Keywords: Incumbents; new entrants; complementary assets; mature industries; innovation
Introduction
Prior research in strategy and innovation management
postulate that incumbent firms have great difficulties in
effectively responding to disruptive changes (Abernathy,
1978; Henderson and Clark, 1990; Christensen and
Rosenbloom, 1995; Hill and Rothaermel, 2003; Benner
and Tripsas, 2012; Cozzolino et al., 2018). This view,
rooted in Schumpeters (1934) notion of creative
destruction, offers two main explanations for the
difficulties of incumbents in responding (Bergek et al.,
2013).
First, incumbents fail when competence-destroying
technologicalinnovations render their existingknowledge
base obsolete. The background is that incumbents are
incentivized to invest in incremental innovation, thus
adding to their established knowledge base and current
stream of rents (Hill and Rothaermel, 2003). A failure to
respond is thus explained by the existence of core
competences (Prahalad and Hamel, 1990) and familiar
technological trajectories (Tushman and Anderson,
1986). Incumbents develop incrementally along a familiar
technological trajectory within a well-understood
technological paradigm (Tripsas, 1997).
The second explanation focuses on customer and
market dynamics that challenge incumbents when new
entrants introduce product attributes that incumbents first
perceive as unimportant. For example, the Swiss
watchmaking industry was almost destroyed by one of
its own inventions, the quartz (Rothaermel, 2001a). New
entrants such as Seiko and Timex were extraordinarily
successful in commercializing this quartz movementin
watches (Jacobides and Winter, 2005). Another example
is Smith Corona, a dominant actor in the typewriter
industry, which failed to adapt to personal computers
and word processing software and went bankrupt as a
result (Hill and Rothaermel, 2003). One last example is
how industry incumbents specializing in bias-ply tire
technology suffered when radial tire technology emerged
(Ansari and Krop, 2012). Incumbent firms that otherwise
do everything right, that is, remain in tune with the
competition, listen to customers, and invest aggressively,
Correspondence: Martin Sköld, Scania Assistant Professor, Stockholm School of Economics, House of Innovation & Scania Research Center, 113 83
Stockholm,Sweden. E-mail martin.skold@hhs.se, +46739094029
DOI: 10.1111/emre.12345
©2019 European Academy of Management
European Management Review, Vol. 17, (2020)
209 5
22,
7
may lose market leadership when confronted with
disruptive changes caused by new technologies
(Christensen, 1997).
However, both explanations are premisedon the notion
that incumbents are incapable of adapting to disruptive
changes, foreseen or unforeseen. However, the type of
change, that is, technological or regulatory, can play a
major role in how incumbents and new entrants respond,
and what the outcomes of those responses will be. Most
prior research on industry disruption has studied
technological change (Christensen, 1997; Kaplan and
Tripsas, 2008; Benner and Tripsas, 2012). However,
regulatory change has also been pointed out as important
because such changes set the boundary conditions for
competition (Rothaermel, 2001b; Jacobides et al., 2006;
Teece, 2006) and can cause environmental shocks (Tee
and Gawer, 2009). Regulatory changes can favor
incumbents because such changes do not necessarily
depreciate the value of core competences. In fact, they
can allow incumbents to pursue incremental innovation
(Ansari and Krop, 2012) and to control existing
ecosystems (Gawer and Cusumano, 2008).
However, regulatory change can also favor new
entrants. When the new Markets in Financial Instruments
Directive (MIFID)regulation in the EU was introduced in
2007 (Degryse, 2009), the new firm Chi-X managed to
quickly capture 1015% of trading volume in major
financial instruments. Chi-X was first to offer a
multilateral trading facility,which could respond to the
demand of executing trades for the best price available
across different capital markets (e.g., Stockholm,
London, and Frankfurt).
1
In a different industry, the US
airline industry,regulatory change in 1978 led to the entry
of low-cost airlines (McGahan and Kou, 1995).
Who is better capable of exploiting market
opportunities when an industry is disrupted by regulatory
changeincumbents or new entrants? To us, that is still
an open question. In cases of technological disruption
the story seems more straightforward. New entrants then
have an advantage because they do not need to account
for invasive patterns or existing competences or modes
of thinking and working. However, regulatory change is
not driven by a technologically disruptive innovation
initiated by a new entrant who uses resources and
knowledge in a new way, but by a regulator. This means
that incumbents and new entrants both need to adapt to a
new situation.
What allows such adaptation? A key factoris the assets
an actor initiallycontrols and develops. Firms withaccess
to the rightcomplementary assets have, in theory, a
distinct advantage to exploit potential value (Tripsas,
1997), and this may hold true when providing products
as well as services (Hill and Rothaermel, 2003; Jacobides
and Winter, 2005;Teece, 2006). Complementary assetsis
thus a framework for explaining why some firms fail to
appropriate returns while others succeed (Funk, 2003;
Colombo et al., 2006; Dahlander and Wallin, 2006). This
framework is especially relevant in industries with weak
appropriabilityregimes (Teece, 1998),that is, in industries
where formal protection of IP provides weak protection.
The life insurance industry is an example of such an
industry.
While prior research is clear on the pivotal role of
complementary assets, it is unclear whether new entrants
or incumbents havea more favorable position to put these
assets to work to manage regulatory changes (Huesig
et al., 2014). It is also unclear how complementary assets
are transformed or reconfigured for exploiting new
business opportunities in times of regulatory change (Hess
and Rothaermel,2011; Teece, 2018). Our study intends to
shed light on these issues.
The rest of the paperis organized as follows. In the next
section, complementary assets are introduced and
reviewed as a framework to determine challenges faced
by incumbents and new entrants in times of regulatory
change. The third section then presents the research
design, sample selection procedure, data collection,
coding, and methods for analysis. Thereafter, data from
a major regulatory change in the life insurance industry
are presented, analyzed, and discussed. The paper
concludes with a discussion of the results as well as
theoretical and managerial implications.
Theoretical background
Complementary assets: Definition and characteristics
Assets are complementary when investments in one
increase the marginal return of the other. For example, if
Tesla, the manufacturer of electric cars, manages to
increase its volume output of cars, that would increase
the marginal returns of their R&D and technology
development. In the strategy and innovation literature,
complementary assets are those needed to support the
commercialization of new products or services but which
are not directly associated with their creation (Teece,
1986; Rothaermel, 2001a).
The idea of complementary assets originated in Teece
(1986), who proposed a theory to explainhow firms profit
from innovation. Teece concluded that assets are a source
of competitive advantage if they are non-tradeable or
supported by a regime of strong appropriability (Teece,
1998). To assess how innovators (new entrants or
incumbents) benefit in regimes of weak appropriability,
Teece proposed the concept of complementary assets
while challenging the notion that being an innovator is
1
https://www.thetradenews.com/chi-x-picks-up-market-share-despite-europe-
wide-dip/
M. Sköld et al.
©2019 European Academy of Management
210

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT