The Causes and Consequences of the Collegial Implementation of European Competition Law

Published date01 September 2013
Date01 September 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/eulj.12035
AuthorYannis Karagiannis
The Causes and Consequences of the
Collegial Implementation of European
Competition Law
Yannis Karagiannis*
Abstract: A major achievement of the new institutionalism is the formalisation of the
idea that certain policies, such as competition law, are more eff‌icient when administered
by a politically independent organisation. Based on this insight, several practitioners and
scholars criticise the European Community for relying too much on a multitask, colle-
gial, and therefore politicised organisation, the European Commission. Def‌ining collegi-
ality as the involvement of non-expert commissioners in the implementation of the EC
competition law, this article offers the f‌irst interdisciplinary analysis of the causes and
consequences of that peculiar European institution. The central f‌inding is that, far from
being a mistake or the product of unanticipated consequences, collegiality was a neces-
sary condition for the creation of supranational European law.
I Introduction
The effectiveness of certain policies is particularly sensitive to their institutional
context. Like monetary policy, competition law is one of them. According to
Richard Posner, ‘whether antitrust policy is sound depends on the enforcement
machinery as well as on legal doctrine. It is not enough to have good doctrine.’1
Partly for that reason, most competition laws in the world are enforced by expert
and independent bureaucracies. For example, in South Africa, ‘the independence of
the competition authorities from the inf‌luence of each other, the state, and private
stakeholders, is now entrenched in the provisions of the Competition Act 89 of
1998’2; in Turkey, ‘the independence of competition authorities has recently been the
cornerstone of institutional reforms’3; and in Asia, the Asian Development Bank has
long argued that ‘the independence of the competition authority, free from the
inf‌luence of the government, is crucial if stakeholders are to believe in the integrity
of the system.’4
* Assistant Professor, Institut Barcelona d’Estudis Internacionals. ykaragiannis@ibei.org.
1R. Posner, Antitrust Law (University of Chicago Press, 2001), at 266.
2Competition Commission of South Africa, Independence and Accountability of Competition Authorities
(UNCTAD Intergovernmental Group of Experts on Competition Law and Policy, 2008).
3Government of the Turkish Republic, Independence and Accountability of Competition Authorities
(UNCTAD Intergovernmental Group of Experts on Competition Law and Policy, 2008).
4Asian Development Bank, Competition Law Toolkit (ADB, Manila, 2007), at 46.
bs_bs_banner
European Law Journal, Vol. 19, No. 5, September 2013, pp. 682–704.
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd., 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ, UK
and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA
Against this background, the institutional architecture of the European Union (not
Community) (‘EU’) anti-trust and merger control competition law seems odd.5Here,
anti-competitive agreements, abuses of market power, and mergers and acquisitions
are not regulated by an expert independent authority but by a collegial Commission.6
Crucially, the Commission comprises members with little or no knowledge of anti-
trust rules, yet the college decides by simple majority rule (Article 250 TFEU) and
without receiving instructions by national governments (Article 245 TFEU). Consider,
for example, the hypothetical case of a merger between two telecommunications
operators. The f‌inal decision does not depend on the equivalent of the Turkish
Rekabet Kurumu, the US Federal Trade Commission, the German Bundeskartellamt
or even some federal ministry of industry. Rather, it depends on a vast, non-expert
and largely unpredictable college, where the vote of the commissioner responsible for
competition counts exactly as much as that of the commissioners responsible for
agriculture, tourism or the budget.7
This article is an attempt to explain the constitutional rule of collegial decision
making in the EC competition law. To do so, I adopt an interdisciplinary perspective
that combines law, economics, political science and history. In a nutshell, I make two
arguments: (1) understanding the origins of that system is crucial for a correct appre-
ciation of its nature and of current debates; and (2) the choice faced by the architects
of Europe’s original (and continuing) institutions was not between having an expert,
independent competition regulator or a collegial system, but between having a com-
petition law or none at all. In other words, because the negotiators of the Treaty of
Paris of 1951 held radically divergent policy preferences, they could only accomplish
their task by consciously creating institutions that could insure each government
against the risk of embarking on an unwarranted adventure dictated by the others.
The collegial enforcement of European competition law was, therefore, neither a
mistake nor a random decision. The demonstration of this point contributes to a
deeper understanding of the context of the EC competition law, possibly bringing it
closer to the level of accumulated knowledge in the US anti-trust.8
In what follows, Section 2 explains the issues posed by the collegial, non-expert
enforcement of the EC competition law.9Section 3 frames these debates using some
standard analytical tools from institutional economics. Section 4 examines a number
of prominent explanatory theories that could be used to interpret the historical
record, and derives their observable implications.10 Section 5 then turns to the his-
torical record of the Paris negotiations of 1950–1951, which led to the creation of the
High Authority of the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC) (the predecessor
5This article focuses on Art 101, Art 102 and merger control, and not on state aids and/or liberalisation.
6For an intra-European comparison, see J. Van de Gronde and S.A. De Vries, ‘Independent Competition
Authorities in the EU’, (2006) 2(1) Utrecht Law Review 32–66.
7For a case where the merger between two aircraft manufacturers was f‌inally decided by the Spanish
commissioner for f‌isheries [sic!], see A. Hill, ‘Brussels Split Over De Havilland Sale’, (1991) Financial
Times, October 1.
8eg R. Bork, ‘Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act’, (1966) 9(1) Journal of Law and
Economics 7–48; F. McChesney and W. Shughart (eds), The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: The
Public Choice Perspective (University of Chicago Press, 1996).
9Of course, were I the f‌irst to observe these problems, this paper would have no reason to be. The
value-added of Sections 2 and 3, therefore, does not reside in their theme, but in the framing of these
issues in terms of the standard concepts of institutional economics.
10 For this methodology, see G. King, R. Keohane and S. Verba, Designing Social Inquiry: Scientif‌ic
Inference in Qualitative Research (Princeton University Press, 1994).
September 2013 Collegiality in EU Anti-Trust
683
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT