The Regulation of Public Procurement as a Key Element of European Economic Law

Date01 June 1998
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0386.00050
Published date01 June 1998
The Regulation of Public Procurement
as a Key Element of
European Economic Law
Christopher Bovis
Abstract:This article aims to investigate the regulation of public purchasing from an
interdisciplinary perspective. It endeavours to provide its audience with the broad
framework of the function of public procurement and public purchasing in the common
market and the Member States, as well as the legal and socio-economic parameters
which determine this newly regulated field. It also intends to enable its readers to
understand and appreciate the impact of the liberalisation of public markets on the
whole process of European integration, as it places the regulation of public
procurement within the framework of the four freedoms, as well as within the EU’s key
policies.
I Public Sector Regulation and the European Integration Process
The Rome Treaty and the amending TEU have envisaged the creation and functioning
of a common market.
1
The European Integration process is primarily an economic
one, with clear political spillover effects from its accomplishment. Not only free and
unobstructed mobility of factors of production (labour and capital),
2
but also the
creation of a single currency and the adoption of a common economic and monetary
policy
3
are required by the Treaties for the accomplishment of their aims. European
integration is based upon a customs union, which will gradually become an economic,
monetary and, finally, a political union. Clearly, the tool for such transformation is
economic integration through the approximation of Member States’ economic policies
and abolition of obstacles to trade. The level of success of economic integration in
Europe will determine the level of success in political integration, as the ultimate
objective stipulated in the Treaties.
As European integration and the establishment and functioning of a genuinely
common market have materialised, the focus of attention of policy and law makers at
both centralised and national levels has concentrated on eliminating non-tariff
barriers that still exist and pose obstacles to the operation of the common market. The
elimination of non-tariff barriers has been the target of European institutions over the
* Deputy Director, Institute of European Public Law, University of Hull. Visiting Professor, Queen’s
University of Belfast.
1
Article 2 EC.
2
Articles 48 and 67 EC respectively.
3
Article 102a EC.
European Law Journal, Vol. 4, No.2, June 1998, pp. 220–242
© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 1998, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK
and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA
Bovis 6 18/8/98 1:18 pm Page 220
past decade, particularly with reference to the completion of the single market project
4
at the end of 1992. European integration, as an economic exercise which was based
upon the concept of a customs union,
5
could only succeed if non-tariff barriers were
abolished. Such responsibility lies predominately in the hands of the Member States,
where, through harmonisation of their legislation and approximation of their
administrative systems,
6
genuinely competitive patterns of trade will bring about the
desirable effects of economic growth and consequently an improvement of working
and living conditions throughout the common market.
7
There have been two strategic plans for the economic integration of the Member
States, which have been implemented by European institutions and transposed to law
and policy by Member States. The first is the abolition of all tariff and non-tariff
obstacles to trade amongst Member States. The second is the establishment of an
effective, workable and undistorted regime of competition within the common market,
where abuse of market dominance and cartelisation could have serious economic
implications in its functioning. The first plan appears to have a static effect aimed at
abolishing all administrative and legal obstacles to free trade and had, as its focal
point, Member States and their national administrations, whereas the second has been
addressed at industry level and has a more on-going and dynamic effect.
All tariff barriers were abolished by the end of the first transitional period,
8
so
customs duties, quotas and other forms of quantitative restrictions could no longer
hinder the free flow of trade between Member States. Non-tariff protection, however,
has proved more difficult to eliminate, as it involves long-established market practices
and patterns that could not change overnight. In the list of non-tariff barriers we
include public monopolies, fiscal factors such as indirect taxation, state aid, technical
standards and, last but not least, public procurement. The above could distort the
operation of the common market and its fundamental freedoms by means other than
tariffs. Trade patterns are hindered as a result of the existence of non-tariff barriers,
and all the attention has been directed on how to eliminate them.
The Commission’s White Paper for the Completion of the Single Market
9
identified
existing non-tariff protection and provided the framework for specific legislative
measures to address the issue at national level. A set of directives was deemed
necessary for the completion of the single market by the end of 1992, and the time
table was set out in the Single European Act, which in fact amended the Rome Treaty
by introducing, inter alia, the concept of the single market. The single market, in
quantifiable terms, could be considered as something less than the common market,
but was perhaps the first and most important part of the latter. As mentioned earlier,
public procurement was pointed out as an actual non-tariff barrier and action was
scheduled to address the issue. The Commission gathered its momentum by referring
to two notable studies,
10
where empirical proof of the distorted market situation in the
June 1998 Regulation of Public Procurement
© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 1998 221
4
White Paper for the Completion of the Internal Market, (COM) 85 310 fin, 1985.
5
Article 9 (1) EC.
6
Cf, Articles 100, 100A, 100B, the latter two being introduced by the SEA.
7
Cf, Articles 2, 3 and 6 of the Rome Treaty.
8
The period from the establishment of the European Communities until 31/12/1969. Cf, Art 8(7) EC.
9
White Paper for the Completion of the Internal Market, (COM) 85 310 fin, 1985.
10
Cf, The Cost of Non-Europe, Basic Findings, Vol 5, Part A; The Cost of Non-Europe in Public Sector
Procurement, (Official Publications of the European Communities, 1988). Also, the Cechinni Report 1992
The European Challenge, (Wildwood House 1988).
Bovis 6 18/8/98 1:18 pm Page 221

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT