Economic impact analysis

AuthorDevelopment Solutions Europe Limited, Directorate-General for Trade (European Commission)
Pages41-92
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
41
2 Economic impact analysis
This section will discuss the economic impact of the GSP on the beneficiary countries. It
will address the following evaluation questions:
i. What has been the impact of the present scheme on developing countries and
LDCs?
ii. What are the factors influencing the achievements observed?
iii. What unintended consequences, if any, can be linked to the design,
implementation, or use of the current GSP?
Firstly, a brief overview of the available evaluations on the economic impact of the
previous GSP will be presented in Section 2.1. Secondly, an overview of tariffs and
preference margins will be presented (Section 2.2.1), as well as detailed analyses of
trade flows under the various components of the GSP (Section 2.2.2). It will contrast
the impact before the introduction of Regulation No.978/2012 (during 2011-2013, which
is referred to as the pre-reform period) with the period of implementation of the
Regulation (2014-2016, which is referred to as the post-reform period). Furthermore,
the section will present econometric estimates of impact of the GSP Regulation using a
gravity modelling approach (Section 2.3) as well as estimates of the determinants of
preference utilisation rates (Section 2.4).
2.1 Lessons learnt from previous evaluations
The expected economic impact of the GSP on the beneficiary countries is premised on
the hypothesis that preferential market access encourages higher economic growth as a
result of increased export opportunities due to lowering market access barriers.
Furthermore, it is expected that preferences may increase exports at the intensive
margin (that is, where countries increase their existing exports), as well as at the
extensive margin (where countries widen or diversify the range of products that are
exported). Along with the EU market providing an economic driver for growth and
development, it is anticipated that beneficiary countries may also benefit from improved
access to regional and global markets, as well as from increased inflows of Foreign Direct
Investment (FDI).
However, it has been noted that participation in a preferential tariff regime is merely one
out of many factors that may propel the growth of an economy. The scheme operates in
an overall bigger context in which trade preferences can only serve a s a facilitator, albeit
a highly significant one, in assisting a beneficiary country to achieve its growth and
development objectives.40
Evaluation studies indicate that the GSP has led to an increase in exports from
developing countries to the EU and has had an overall positive effect on the economic
and social development of the respective countries.41 However, the level of exports to
the EU differs a great deal among GSP beneficiaries. In 2010, it was found that the EU
imports under the GSP from East Asia, the Pacific and South Asia are significantly
greater than any other countries or regions included in the GSP.42
40CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences, p. 12.
41CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences. Rahman M. (2014). Trade
Benefits for Least Developed Countries: the Bangladesh Case. Available at:
http://www.un.org/en/development/desa/policy/cdp/cdp_background_papers/bp2014_18.pdf. Copenhagen
Economics.(2015). Assessment of Economic Benefits Generated by the EU Trade Regimes towards the
Developing Countries. Available at: http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2015/july/tradoc_153595.pdf
42CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences.
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
42
It was also observed that the economic impact of the EU’s GSP in the beneficiary
countries is measurable after a relatively short period of time. The Copenhagen
Economics study on the economic benefits generated by the GSP arrangement in
developing countries finds that the sizeable impact on exports is recognizable, on
average, within two years after preferences have been granted.43
Importantly, the share of total EU imports which entered under the GSP is relatively
modest. In 2008, under the previous GSP Regulation, only 5.1 per cent of total EU
imports were under GSP, with imports under the Standard GSP arrangement accounting
for 4.18 per cent, while 0.46 per cent and 0.46 per cent of EU imports entered under
GSP+ and EBA arrangements, respectively.
The GSP i ntends to stimulate a beneficiary country’s economic growth by wideni ng their
preference margins, thereby contributing to the respective country’s competitiveness.
However, as trade barriers are generally lowered via multilateral trade liberalization as
well as regional or bilateral FTAs, the value of the GSP trade preferences is bound to
diminish. Several studies have paid attention to this development of preference erosion
and have investigated the changes of preference margins over time.44
Research on the impact of trade preferences under the previous GSP Regulation noted
that there were a significant number of sectors where GSP preferences had been
completely eroded and several exports from GSP beneficiary countries utilise the full
Most Favoured Nation (MFN) tariff (i.e. where the MFN tariff is equal to zero).45 For
example, a case study on Mozambique, presented in the 2010 Mid-Term Evaluation of
the EU ’s GSP Report, suggests that the impact of t he pr eference regi me is likely to be
overstated, because a significant number of products exported by developing countries
do not benefit from any positive preferential margin since they enter the EU under MFN
= 0 duties.46 This has significant implications for the impact of the GSP, which critically
depends “on the extent of that preference margin, as well as on the relationship between
that margin, and the incentive for firms and countries to utilise the preferences on
offer.47
There are some differences in opinions in the evaluation literature as to where eventual
tariff margins and preference rents are absorbed. Some case studies, like the one on
Mozambique, argue that exporters may be unable to capture the price margin related to
the trade preferences.48 Other studies contest this and indicate that export prices and
the preference rents of the decreased tariffs are at least partly captured by the
exporters.49 The CARIS 2 010 eval uation states that both market share and the size of
the preference margin are positively transmitted to the price margin, which suggests
that preference margins are transmitted to exporters.50
The evaluation literature further suggests that the EU’s GSP has had a positive impact on
countries’ export diversification. The theoretical expl anations for this exp ected benefit
are rooted in the infant industry assumption as well as the more recent heterogeneous
43Copenhagen Economics. (2015). Assessment of Economic Benefits Generated by the EU Trade Regimes
Towards the Developing Countries, p. 17.
44CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences; Cirera, X. (2010).The
Impact of Trade Preferences on Export Prices in the European Union Who Captures the Preference Rent?
45Cirera, X. (2010).The Impact of Trade Preferences on Export Prices in the European Union Who Captures
the Preference Rent?p. 22.
46Cirera, X. and Alfieri, A. (2011).Unilateral Trade Preferences in the EU: An Empirical Assessment for the Case
of Mozambican Exports, p. 9.
47CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences, p. 13.
48Cirera, X. and Alfieri, A. (2011).Unilateral Trade Preferences in the EU: An Empirical Assessment for the Case
of Mozambican Exports, p. 9.
49CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences, p. 69; Cirera, X.
(2010).The Impact of Trade Preferences on Export Prices in the European Union Who Captures the
Preference Rent?
50CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences, p. 96.
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
43
firm trade theory. In short, both theoretical perspectives place importance on
preferential treatment for young recently established industries. In doing so, it is
suggested that through the reduction of trade barriers, more firms and producers a re
encouraged to export.
Trade preferences have often also been criticized for creating an incentive to specialize in
a few products that are given preferential access or prevent the beneficiary countries
from adopting more liberal trade policies. Gamberoni (2007) suggests that unilateral
trade preferences have led to an anti-diversification effect in the case when preferences
have been granted under permanent and stable schemes.51 Nevertheless, the 2013 IFN
study on the EU’s i mpact on export diversifi cation suggests that the EBA and GSP+ have
had a significantly positive effect on export diversification.52
The evaluation literature on the utilisation of preferences show that the majority of EU
imports from developing countries enters the EU under zero duties and that EU
preferences are well used.53In cases where preference utilisation is low, the volume of
imports dutiable and hence potentially eligible for preferences is also often low. An
exception appears to be EU imports of textiles and textile articles from the non-ACPs
LDC and from ASEAN, which may be related to restrictive EU Rules of Origin (RoO) in
that particular sector, rather than it being a general phenomenon. Around 90 per cent of
preference-eligible imports in Canada, the EU and the US use available preferences.54
Preference utilisation was also found to increase depending on the size of the preferential
margin and the export value.55 Additionally, where the utilisation of preferences was low,
it was found that the preferential margin was small, thus suggesting that compliance
costs may be low but not negligible. Nevertheless, it should also be noted that many
imports with small preferential margins feature high utilisation rates, even where
significant administrative costs exist.56
The literature further explains that non-utilisation of preferences is mainly due to the
costs of compliance associated to preferential regimes. 57 An important element to
consider is compliance with product specific rules of origin. In order to be eligible for
preferential treatment, exporters need to comply with rules that establish a minimum
threshold of domestic transformation in the production process from inputs imported
abroad. While trying to avoid export deflection of finished products from non-preferential
countries, rules of origin may indirectly discourage some forms of outward processing
and outsourcing as these would be categorized as originating in non-preferential
partners. The absence of the relevant local production capacity for such inputs would
effectively render certain locally-produced finished goods (despite being covered by the
trade agreement) ineligible for preferential market access. 58This may have affected a
substantial share of trade flows.
51 Gamberoni, E. (2007) Do unilateral trade preferences help export diversification? An investigation of the
impact of European unilateral trade preferences on the extensive and intensive margin of trade. HEI Working
Paper, No. 17/2007
52Persson, M. and Wilhemsson, F. (2013).EU Trade Preferences and Export Diversification, p. 25.
53Nilsson, L. & Mattson, N. (2009) Truths and myths about the openness of EU trade policy and
the use of EU trade preferences.
54Keck, A. and Lendle, A. (2012).New evidence on preference utilisation.World Trade Organization
Economic Research and Statistics Division, Staff Working Paper ERSD-2012-12
55Candau, F., et al. (2004).The utilisation rate of preferences in the EU.
56Keck, A. and Lendle, A. (2012).New evidence on preference utilisation.World Trade Organization
Economic Research and Statistics Division, Staff Working Paper ERSD-2012-12
57CARIS.(2010). Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU’s Generalised System of Preferences. Nilsson, Lars. (2015). EU
exports and uptake of preferences: A First Analysis. Keck, A. and Lendle, A. (2012).New evidence on
preference utilisation.World Trade Organization
Economic Research and Statistics Division, Staff Working Paper ERSD-2012-12
58Eckart, N. (2006). Comparing EU free trade agreements: Rules of Origin.In Brief, No. 61. Available at:
http://ecdpm.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/11/IB-6I-Comparing-EU-Free-Trade-Agreements-Rules-of-Origin-
2006.pdf .

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT