What Roles for Which Stakeholders under Extended Producer Responsibility?

AuthorReid Lifset,Chris Van Rossem,Harri Kalimo,Atalay Atasu,Luk Van Wassenhove
Date01 April 2015
Published date01 April 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/reel.12087
What Roles for Which Stakeholders under Extended
Producer Responsibility?
Harri Kalimo,* Reid Lifset, Atalay Atasu, Chris Van Rossem
and Luk Van Wassenhove
This article analyzes extended producer responsibility
(EPR), two decades after the concept emerged. It con-
centrates on the scope of the producers’ responsibility
vis-à-vis other stakeholders in the context of EPR for
waste electronics. It argues that in order for a core
aspect of EPR – the creation of design incentives – to
function properly the responsibilities need to be shared
between the producers and other stakeholders, and
that the allocation of responsibilities needs to be both
more rigorous and more nuanced than is presently the
case. The article structures the discussion on, and pres-
ents solutions to, the proper allocation of responsibili-
ties by creating a framework that distinguishes
between issues relating to the core premises of EPR,
those that are a function of the multilevel system of
governance in which EPR is pursued, and those that
are of a practical nature, cutting across jurisdictional
levels.
INTRODUCTION
Despite considerable improvements in some countries,
recent statistics suggest that a resource-efficient recy-
cling society is still largely an elusive goal.1Public
authorities continue their quest for policies that would
effectively address the depletion of nonrenewable
materials, reduce emissions to air and water, prevent
the creation of waste as well as improve the recycling
and end-of-life management of products. In essence,
waste management activities need to be moved up the
waste hierarchy from sound disposal to recycling, reuse
and ultimately prevention.2An important instrument in
this pursuit is extended producer responsibility (EPR),
through which the private sector can be directly
engaged in greening the economy.
EPR as a concept was put forward by academics in the
early 1990s. The rationale behind it is quite simple: by
assigning producers financial and/or physical respon-
sibility for the management of end-of-life products,
they are led to internalize waste management consider-
ations into their overall product strategies. Rational
producers explore options to minimize the costs of end-
of-life management. Alterations in product design and
choice of material are among the most important
means to do so, and are essential for reducing the envi-
ronmental impact of products. EPR, in other words, is
one means of generating both economic and political
incentives for recovery and, more broadly, green
design.3It is our view that the central rationale for EPR
should be the creation of incentives for improved envi-
ronmental design of products (DfE4). This analysis of
the scope of producer responsibilities is premised on
that view.
The origins of the term ‘extended producer responsi-
bility’ can be traced to a report submitted to the
Swedish Ministry of the Environment in 1990.5
The development of the concept may be viewed in the
context of three general trends in environmental law-
and policy-making at the time:6the prioritization of
preventive measures over end-of-pipe approaches;
life-cycle thinking; and a shift from command and
control towards instruments such as economic and
informational tools, which leave more flexibility in
terms of how the set policy objectives are to be
* Corresponding author: Harri Kalimo, Institute for European Studies,
Vrije Universiteit Brussel, Pleinlaan 5, B-1050 Brussels, Belgium.
Email: Harri.Kalimo@vub.ac.be
1See Commission of the European Union Report on the Thematic
Strategy on the Prevention and Recycling of Waste, COM(2011) 13.
2The waste management hierarchy is a heuristic that specifies that
waste should be managed according to a set of priorities: reduction,
reuse, recycling and disposal. The European Union has adopted the
hierarchy as a principle for the management of waste. See Directive
2008/98/EC of 19 November 2008 on Waste and Repealing Certain
Directives, [2008] OJ L312/3, recital 1 and Article 4.
3R. Lifset, ‘Take it Back: Extended Producer Responsibility as a Form
of Incentive Based Environmental Policy’, 21:4 Journal of Resource
Management and Technology (1993), 163.
4Design for environment, also called ‘eco-design’, refers to the
design of products in a way that reduces the negative impacts of the
product on the environment throughout the product’s life cycle.
5T. Lindhqvist and K. Lidgren, Modeller för förlängt producent-
ansvar: Från vaggan till graven – sex studier av varors miljöpåverkan
(Ministry of the Environment, 1991).
6N. Tojo, Extended Producer Responsibility as a Driver for Design
Change: Utopia or Reality? (IIIEE Dissertations 2004:2, Lund Univer-
sity, 2004).
bs_bs_banner
Review of European Community & International Environmental Law
RECIEL 24 (1) 2015. ISSN 2050-0386 DOI: 10.1111/reel.12087
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
40
achieved. These three trends merge in the central idea
of extended producer responsibility: to create green
design incentives for producers.7
This article analyzes the creation of design incentives
two decades after the emergence of the concept, and
with over 400 EPR systems in operation globally.8We
focus specifically on the scope of the producers’ respon-
sibility – in other words, the division of roles between
producers and other stakeholders in the creation of
design incentives. The question of roles is critical in the
context of today’s complex, global economies. A large
number of public and private stakeholders interact in
environmental law and policy frameworks that have
evolved into deliberative processes of multiple levels of
governance and transnational networks. If the design
incentives are lost in the maze of actors and policies, a
core rationale for EPR is lost.9
The article frames its discussion against the practical
case of electrical and electronic equipment (EEE). This
group of products epitomizes global markets, and EEE
is perhaps the most prominent area where EPR is
being applied today. The leading piece of legislation in
the field – the WEEE Directive of the European Union
(EU)10 – has been comprehensively recast. The analy-
sis will not only offer insights on EPR and its evolu-
tion; it also serves more generally as a case for
portraying the challenges facing second-generation
environmental law and policy tools in greening the
global economy.
The narrative in this article proceeds on four fronts in
the discussion of the roles of producers and other stake-
holders in creating design incentives in EPR. First, it
seeks to clarify key concepts that define the roles of the
parties in EPR. The concepts have evolved and some-
times become blurred during the practical implemen-
tation of EPR. Second, the article aims to systematize
the overall EPR discourse by developing a multilevel
governance-based framework of analysis.11 Third,
drawing on these conceptual and analytical frame-
works, the article analyzes the roles assigned to the
different stakeholders so as to identify the most promi-
nent challenges to creating product design incentives in
EPR. These are issues that risk undermining the
broader EPR system or severely impeding it from func-
tioning. They should therefore be at the top of the policy
debate and agenda. The goal of the article is to bring
clarity and structure to the analysis of EPR and to
suggest possible policy paths for further exploration
rather than to advance specific remedies. While the
focus is on the WEEE Directive and its recast, the analy-
sis makes use of practical experiences that have accu-
mulated in EPR policies more broadly in the EU, but
also in the United States.
The problems relating to design incentives can be
explored in terms of two important aspects of the
stakeholders’ roles: the allocation of extended respon-
sibility among the producers, on the one hand, and the
division between the producers’ and other stakehold-
ers’ responsibility, on the other. The issues regarding
the allocation of responsibilities among the producers
are discussed in a companion article;12 this analysis
focuses on the latter topic. In particular, it examines
the following questions: What should fall within the
scope of a producer’s responsibility and what should
fall within the responsibility of other stakeholders?
What exactly should the producers be (and not be)
responsible for? What kind of (ancillary) responsibili-
ties should be allocated to other stakeholders? What
are the appropriate mechanisms for allocating such
responsibilities?
The article proposes a new, more systematic framework
for analyzing EPR. Although there is increasing
research on EPR and its shortcomings, the scholarship
often either focuses on isolated issues or gives an
7While the term ‘producers’ is often taken to mean manufacturers,
the entity in the upstream portion of the product life cycle that is
assigned responsibility under EPR varies across jurisdictions and
product categories and can include material suppliers, brand owners
and retailers. The identification of the producer is discussed below.
8P. Börkey, ‘What Have We Learned about Extended Producer
Responsibility in the Past Decade?’. Presentation at the Conference
of ACR+ & Brussels Environment EPR (R)evolution in the European
Context (Brussels, 19 September 2013).
9T, Lindhqvist and R. Lifset, ‘Can We Take the Concept of Individual
Producer Responsibility from Theory to Practice?’, 7:2 Journal of
Industrial Ecology (2003), 3, at 3.
10 The original law, Directive 2002/96/EC of 27 January 2003 on
Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE), [2003] OJ L37/
24, is referred to in this article as the ‘WEEE Directive’. When the new
revised law or its provisions are distinguished from the original law,
Directive 2012/19/EU of 4 July 2012 on Waste Electrical and Elec-
tronic Equipment (WEEE) (recast), [2012] OJ L197/38, they are
referred to as the ‘Recast WEEE Directive’.
11 Multilevel governance has been developed by authors such as
Rhodes (e.g., R.A.W. Rhodes, ‘The New Governance: Governing
without Government’, 44:4 Political Studies (1996), 652) and Hooghe
and Marks (e.g., L. Hooghe and G. Marks, Multi-Level Governance
and European Integration (Rowman & Littlefield, 2001)) as a model to
explain policy developments in the EU in particular. The model deals
with the optimal levels of governance through the scale of the
problem and the stakeholders affected by it, while also acknowledg-
ing the externalities at stake. Multilevel governance has subsequently
been applied to various areas of environmental law and policy in the
EU and beyond.
12 The two pieces share the same analytical framework. They are part
of an ongoing research effort to explore how incentives for DfE may
be realized or enhanced. In addition to H. Kalimo et al. (‘Greening the
Economy through Design Incentives: Allocating Extended Producer
Responsibility’, 21:6 European Energy and Environmental Law
Review (2012), 274), Dempsey et al. examine the extent to which
existing EPR systems contain elements of individual producer
responsibility (M. Dempsey et al., ‘Individual Producer Responsibility:
A Review of Practical Approaches to Implementing Individual Pro-
ducer Responsibility for the WEEE Directive’ (INSEAD, 2010)).
RECIEL 24 (1) 2015 EXTENDED PRODUCER RESPONSIBILITY
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
41

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT